Close
About
FAQ
Home
Collections
Login
USC Login
Register
0
Selected
Invert selection
Deselect all
Deselect all
Click here to refresh results
Click here to refresh results
USC
/
Digital Library
/
University of Southern California Dissertations and Theses
/
The power of flexibility: autonomous agents that conserve energy in commercial buildings
(USC Thesis Other)
The power of flexibility: autonomous agents that conserve energy in commercial buildings
PDF
Download
Share
Open document
Flip pages
Contact Us
Contact Us
Copy asset link
Request this asset
Transcript (if available)
Content
The Power of Flexibility: Autonomous Agents That Conserve Energy
in Commercial Buildings
by
Jun-young Kwak
A Dissertation Presented to the
FACULTY OF THE USC GRADUATE SCHOOL
UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHERN CALIFORNIA
In Partial Fulfillment of the
Requirements for the Degree
DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY
(Computer Science)
May 2014
Copyright 2014 Jun-young Kwak
Acknowledgments
First and foremost, I would like to thank my advisor, Professor Milind Tambe, director of the
TEAMCORE research group. When I first joined, I literally had no idea what the definition of a
good advisor was, but it did not take too long for me to realize how lucky I was to have chosen to
work with Milind. Milind is a great advisor and one of the smartest and most creative people I
know. I hope that I can be as lively, enthusiastic, and energetic as him and someday be able to
command an audience as well as he can. Milind has been supportive and has given me the freedom
to pursue various projects without objection. He has also provided insightful discussions about the
research and has taught me new ways of thinking throughout my PhD tenure. In addition to our
academic collaboration, I greatly value the close personal support that Milind has provided over
the years. Quite simply I cannot imagine a better advisor.
Next, I would also like to thank my co-advisor, Professor Pradeep Varakantham at Singapore
Management University. He has been a great advisor, mentor, and friend ever since we met
at Carnegie Mellon University. I remember the short conversation with Pradeep at CMU has
eventually led me to USC and the TEAMCORE research group. I appreciate all of the time
and ideas he contributed to make my PhD experience productive and stimulating. The joy and
enthusiasm Pradeep has for his research was contagious and motivational for me throughout
ii
my time at USC. I am also thankful for the excellent example he has provided as a successful
researcher and professor.
Of course I gratefully acknowledge the other members of my dissertation guidance committee
for their time and valuable feedback on my research and thesis. In a line of research at the
intersection of many disciplines, my interdisciplinary committee could not have been more perfect
for shaping and pushing my research to the heights I have been able to achieve. My sincerest
gratitude to you all: Rajiv Maheswaran, Yu-Han Chang, Burcin Becerik-Gerber, and Wendy Wood.
During my time at USC I have also had the honor to work with many great researchers: Amos
Freedy, David Gerber, David Kempe, Matthew Taylor, Christopher Kiekintveld, Janusz Marecki,
Rong Yang, Nan Li, Timothy Hayes, Farrokh Jazizadeh, Georey Kavulya, Laura Klein, and Onur
Sert.
I would also like to thank the rest of the TEAMCORE community, particularly those that I
have had the pleasure of spending my PhD career with: James Pita, Fei Fang, Thanh Nguyen,
Leandro Marcolino, Chao Zhang, Yundi Qian, Debarun Kar, Benjamin Ford, Haifeng Xu, Amulya
Yadav, Albert Jiang, Francesco Delle Fave, William Haskell, Bo An, Gal Kaminka, Nathan Schurr,
and Jagrut Sharma. I would particularly like to thank Manish Jain for being the best ocemate
I could ask for, for all of your advice over the years, and for being a great friend even during
tough times in the PhD pursuit; Jason Tsai for being the sincere best friend who have spent infinite
nights together to have dinner/drinks while sharing many dierent thoughts, and for proofreading
my terrible writing millions of times without any complaints (I still owe you a lot of beers, so
whenever you feel thirsty, come down see me!); Zhengyu Yin for solving millions of mathematical
problems for me and for your great sense of humor; Matthew Brown for being a great neighbor
and friend in the apartment and in the oce, for having provided valuable comments over the
iii
years, and for being a new drinks companion in K-town!; and Paul Scerri for being a source of
friendship as well as good advice and collaboration since we met at CMU. In addition, my time
at USC was made enjoyable in large part due to the many friends and groups that became a part
of my life: Maxim Makatchev, Mihail Pivtoraiko, Prasanna Velagapudi, William Yeoh and Chan
Seol.
Finally, I want to thank my family for all their love and encouragement. In particular, thank
you to my parents for supporting and undoubtedly believing me. Lastly, I would like to thank my
beautiful life companion Yu Jeong for coming into my life, being my best friend as well as a life
mentor. I could not express more of my gratefulness in words for your patience, kindness, faithful
support and love. Thank you.
iv
Table of Contents
Acknowledgments ii
List of Figures viii
List of Tables xi
Abstract xiii
Chapter 1: Introduction 1
1.1 Problem Addressed . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
1.2 Contributions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.3 Guide to Thesis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
Chapter 2: Background 13
2.1 Markov Decision Problems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
2.2 Cooperative Game Theory and the Shapley Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
2.3 Educational Building Testbeds . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
2.3.1 The actual testbed building for SA VES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
2.3.2 The actual testbed buildings for TESLA & THINC . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
2.4 Simulation Testbed . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
2.4.1 Building Components . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20
2.4.2 Human Occupants . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
2.4.3 Validation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
2.5 Data Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
Chapter 3: SA VES 30
3.1 Agents in SA VES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
3.2 Multi-objective MDPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
3.3 BM-MDPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
3.4 Evaluation of SA VES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38
3.4.1 Simulation: Overall Evaluation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38
3.4.1.1 Result: Total Energy Consumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
3.4.1.2 Result: Average Satisfaction Level . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
3.4.2 Simulation: Multi-objective Optimization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
3.4.3 Real-world Test: Human Experiments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
v
Chapter 4: TESLA 48
4.1 TESLA Architecture . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
4.2 TESLA Algorithms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
4.2.1 Scheduling algorithms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
4.2.2 Identifying key meetings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
4.3 Empirical Validation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
4.3.1 Simulation Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
4.3.1.1 Does flexibility help? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
4.3.1.2 Online scheduling method with flexibility: Determining the
sample size in the TESLA SMILP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
4.3.1.3 Performance of online scheduling method with flexibility . . . 64
4.3.1.4 Performance of identifying key meetings . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
4.3.1.5 Considering the cancellation rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
4.4 Analysis: Savings due to TESLA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72
4.4.1 HV ACs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72
4.4.2 Lighting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
4.4.3 Electronics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
4.5 Human Subject Experiments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
4.5.1 Survey for initial flexibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
4.5.2 Survey for requested flexibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
Chapter 5: THINC 84
5.1 Fair Division of Credit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84
5.1.1 Approximate Shapley computation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87
5.1.2 Approximate characteristic value computation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
5.2 THINC Rescheduling Algorithm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
5.3 Empirical Validation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94
5.3.1 Shapley Value Evaluation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
5.3.1.1 Fair Division: Why Shapley Value? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
5.3.1.2 Approximation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
5.3.2 Performance of replanning BM-MDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
5.3.3 Deployed Application . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
Chapter 6: Related Work 103
6.1 Agent-based Systems in Energy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104
6.2 Robust MDP and Multi-objective Optimization Techniques . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
6.3 Resource Allocation and Scheduling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107
6.4 Fair Division in Cooperative Game Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108
6.4.1 Cooperative Game Theory in Energy Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108
6.4.2 Shapley Value and Approximation Techniques . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
6.5 Social Influence in Human Subject Studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111
Chapter 7: Conclusions 113
7.1 Contributions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114
7.2 Future Work . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117
vi
Bibliography 120
Appendix: Properties of Shapley Value to Axiomatize Fairness 129
vii
List of Figures
2.1 Real Testbed Buildings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
2.2 The current room reservation system at the testbed building . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
2.3 Screen Capture of the Simulation Testbed . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
2.4 Parameter Values for Energy Calculation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
2.5 RGL Floor Plan (2
nd
& 3
rd
floors of the testbed building) . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
2.6 Actual Temperature Preference . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
2.7 Energy Consumption Validation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
2.8 Real data analysis (USC) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
2.9 Real data analysis (SMU) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
3.1 Agents & Communication Equipment in SA VES. An agent in SA VES sends
feedback including energy use to occupants. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
3.2 Performance Evaluation of SA VES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
3.3 Performance of BM-MDPs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
4.1 TESLA architecture: TESLA is a continuously running agent that supports four
key features: (i) energy-ecient scheduling; (ii) identification of key meetings;
(iii) learning of user preferences; and (iv) communication with users. . . . . . . . 48
4.2 Disjoint sets of R . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
viii
4.3 Energy savings: Actual - the amount of energy consumed in simulation based on
the past schedules obtained from the current manual reservation system; Random
- energy consumption while randomly perturbing the starting time and location
of meeting requests from the same past schedules while keeping meeting time
duration; Optimal - Energy consumption measured in simulation based on optimal
schedules computed from an SMILP with the fully known meeting request set and
full flexibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
4.4 Scalability and accuracy while varying the number of samples (N) . . . . . . . . 63
4.5 Energy savings while varying flexibility (USC) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
4.6 Energy savings while varying flexibility (SMU) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68
4.7 Average energy improvement while considering the cancellation rate of meeting
requests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
4.8 Energy savings by TESLA: the percentage of energy savings per each energy
consumer and factor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72
4.9 Energy saving analysis: room size . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73
4.10 Energy savings only by HV ACs (Non-peak Time) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73
4.11 Screenshot of online survey: people were asked to indicate their meeting requests
and flexibility. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
4.12 Diversity of people’s flexibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
5.1 THINC architecture . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84
5.2 Illustrative example: L
i
& T
i
mean available rooms and time slots, respectively. Each
meeting request r
i
has a set of preferred locations and time, which indicates location and
time flexibility. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86
5.3 Runtime comparison – S: Sampling (# of samples), C: Caching, P: Partitioning (#
of partitions), L: LP Relaxation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
5.4 Solution quality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
5.5 Average deviation (%) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
5.6 Eciency violation (%) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
5.7 Solution quality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
ix
5.8 Measured users’ flexibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
x
List of Tables
2.1 Parameter Description for Energy Calculation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
2.2 Parameter Values for Energy Calculation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
2.3 Energy consumption validation (kWh) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
2.4 Meeting request arrival distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
3.1 Average Maximum Regret Comparison . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
3.2 Example of the Meeting Relocation Negotiation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
3.3 Lighting Negotiation Results (*: p< 0.05) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46
4.1 Performance comparison between SAA and myopic . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65
4.2 % of optimal energy savings: varying
T
,
L
, and p
f
(USC) . . . . . . . . . . . 67
4.3 Percentage of optimal energy savings: varying
d
(USC) . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67
4.4 Percentage of optimal energy savings: varying
d
(SMU) . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
4.5 Energy improvement of identified key meetings (%) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
4.6 Basic Profile Questionnaire . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
4.7 Survey I: Questionnaire . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
4.8 Survey II: Questionnaire . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
4.9 Flexibility manipulation with various feedback (%) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83
5.1 Runtime Comparison (hours) – In conjunction with caching & LP relaxation (# of meetings:
100) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
xi
5.2 Rescheduling real meetings: uncertainty in user reactions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101
xii
Abstract
Agent-based systems for energy conservation are now a growing area of research in multiagent
systems, with applications ranging from energy management and control on the smart grid, to
energy conservation in residential buildings, to energy generation and dynamic negotiations in
distributed rural communities. Contributing to this area, my thesis presents new agent-based
models and algorithms aiming to conserve energy in commercial buildings.
More specifically, my thesis provides three sets of algorithmic contributions. First, I provide
online predictive scheduling algorithms to handle massive numbers of meeting/event scheduling
requests considering flexibility, which is a novel concept for capturing generic user constraints
while optimizing the desired objective. Second, I present a novel BM-MDP (Bounded-parameter
Multi-objective Markov Decision Problem) model and robust algorithms for multi-objective
optimization under uncertainty both at the planning and execution time. The BM-MDP model
and its robust algorithms are useful in (re)scheduling events to achieve energy eciency in the
presence of uncertainty over user’s preferences. Third, when multiple users contribute to energy
savings, fair division of credit for such savings to incentivize users for their energy saving activities
arises as an important question. I appeal to cooperative game theory and specifically to the concept
of Shapley value for this fair division. Unfortunately, scaling up this Shapley value computation is
a major hindrance in practice. Therefore, I present novel approximation algorithms to eciently
xiii
compute the Shapley value based on sampling and partitions and to speed up the characteristic
function computation.
These new models have not only advanced the state of the art in multiagent algorithms, but
have actually been successfully integrated within agents dedicated to energy eciency: SA VES,
TESLA and THINC. SA VES focuses on the day-to-day energy consumption of individuals and
groups in commercial buildings by reactively suggesting energy conserving alternatives. TESLA
takes a long-range planning perspective and optimizes overall energy consumption of a large
number of group events or meetings together. THINC provides an end-to-end integration within
a single agent of energy ecient scheduling, rescheduling and credit allocation. While SA VES,
TESLA and THINC thus dier in their scope and applicability, they demonstrate the utility of
agent-based systems in actually reducing energy consumption in commercial buildings.
I evaluate my algorithms and agents using extensive analysis on data from over 110,000 real
meetings/events at multiple educational buildings including the main libraries at the University
of Southern California. I also provide results on simulations and real-world experiments, clearly
demonstrating the power of agent technology to assist human users in saving energy in commercial
buildings.
xiv
Chapter 1: Introduction
Limited availability of energy sources has led to the need to develop ecient measures of conserv-
ing energy and has raised broad interests in building agent-based systems for real world energy
applications. Motivated by this need, researchers in the multiagent community have successfully
developed agent-based systems for saving energy both in the smart grid and in buildings [Stein
et al., 2012; Mamidi et al., 2012b; Kamboj et al., 2011; Ramchurn et al., 2011; Rogers et al., 2011;
V oice et al., 2011; Bapat et al., 2011; Sou et al., 2011; Xiong et al., 2011].
More specifically, sustainable production, delivery and use of energy in the smart grid and
buildings has now become an important challenge. The distributed nature of the energy grid
and the individual interests of users makes multiagent modeling an appropriate approach for
this problem. For instance, intelligent systems in the smart grid eciently predict the use of
energy and dynamically optimize its delivery [Vytelingum et al., 2010; Ramchurn et al., 2011].
A game-theoretic framework for modeling storage devices in large-scale systems where each
storage device is owned by a self-interested agent that aims to maximize its monetary profit [V oice
et al., 2011; Vandael et al., 2011]. Multiagent systems have been also widely employed to
model home automation systems (or smart homes) and simulating control algorithms to evaluate
performance [Rogers et al., 2011; Abras et al., 2006; Conte and Scaradozzi, 2003; Roy et al.,
1
2006]. This research has given rise to a new area of agent-based systems for energy conservation.
Contributing to this area, my thesis presents new agent-based models and algorithms aiming
at conserving energy in commercial (including oce and educational) buildings, given their
significant energy consumption.
1.1 Problem Addressed
Reducing energy consumption is an important goal for sustainability. Conserving energy in
commercial buildings is important as these buildings are responsible for significant energy con-
sumption. In 2008, commercial buildings in the U.S. consumed 18.5 QBTU
1
, representing 46.2%
of building energy consumption and 18.4% of U.S. energy consumption [U.S. Department of
Energy, 2010]. Such rapid growth in energy usage from commercial buildings has made the need
for systems that aid in reducing energy consumption a top priority.
Researchers have been developing multiagent systems to conserve energy for deployment in
smart grids and buildings [Kamboj et al., 2011; Mamidi et al., 2012a; Miller et al., 2012; Ramchurn
et al., 2011; Rogers et al., 2011; Stein et al., 2012; Bapat et al., 2011; Sou et al., 2011; Xiong et al.,
2011]. However, their work has been done with a particular focus on residential buildings, and that
work does not directly apply to commercial buildings. For instance, those approaches focus on
flexible scheduling of household appliances, or presenting techniques for home automation [Bapat
et al., 2011; Mohsenian-Rad and Leon-Garcia, 2010; Sou et al., 2011; Wang et al., 2009; Xiong
et al., 2011]. More discussion will follow in the related work section.
1
QBTU indicates Quadrillion BTU, which is used as the common unit to explain global energy use. 1 BTU =
0.00029 kWh.
2
While the goal of a sustainable energy system is the same in both commercial and residential
buildings (i.e., eciently conserving energy), three unique research challenges should be simulta-
neously addressed for successfully saving energy in commercial buildings. First, algorithms should
be able to handle massive meetings/events schedules while focusing on conserving energy and
considering the given human models. Second, the types of energy-related behaviors in commercial
buildings are dierent from residential buildings and require agents to negotiate with groups of
people for guiding their behaviors to conserve further energy (e.g., scheduling group activities
such as meetings). Thus, energy systems in commercial buildings should harness changes in
people’s energy related behaviors while ensuring a balance of energy savings and comfort (i.e.,
multi-objective optimization). However, there may be uncertainty in people’s preferences regard-
ing such group activities, and thus the system may not be able to directly learn those preference
models (i.e., model uncertainty). Third, algorithms should also ensure that proper credit is given
based on people’s true contribution to the energy savings in order to eectively motivate people in
a shared place (i.e., fair credit).
1.2 Contributions
The key insight underlying my thesis is that adding flexibility to meeting/event schedules in
commercial buildings can lead to significant energy savings. Such savings can then be divided
amongst the group of people who provided flexibility to incentivize further savings. In the long
run, via my agent-based systems, people are sustainably encouraged to provide more flexibility by
incentives that come from savings caused by such flexibility. In this context, my thesis presents new
agent-based models and algorithms aiming to conserve energy in commercial buildings. My three
3
algorithmic contributions are: (i) performing predictive scheduling on massive number of group
events while considering human users’ behavior preferences and constraints; (ii) interacting with
human users to gain further savings by changing their given behavior and in particular scheduling
preferences; and (iii) dividing up such credit of energy savings in a fair manner as part of an
incentive mechanism.
The first contribution of my thesis handles online predictive scheduling of massive numbers
of dynamically arriving and uncertain meetings/events while considering flexibility, which is a
novel concept for capturing generic user constraints [Kwak et al., 2013a,b]. In reality, uncertainty
is prevalent in the context of scheduling due to lack of accurate prediction models and data.
Therefore, it is of crucial importance to develop systematic methods to address the problem of
scheduling under uncertainty, in order to create ecient and reliable schedules while satisfying the
given objective. To that end, I propose a novel robust optimization approach for scheduling a large
number of meetings while considering (i) flexibility in meeting requests over time, location and
deadlines; and (ii) user preferences with respect to multiple objectives (e.g., energy and comfort).
More specifically, I provide the following algorithmic contribution: a two-stage stochastic mixed
integer linear program (SMILP) for energy-ecient scheduling of incrementally/dynamically
arriving meetings and events.
Stochastic programming has provided a framework for modeling optimization problems that
involve uncertainty [Beale, 1955; Dantzig, 1955; Kall and Wallace, 1994; Shapiro et al., 2009].
Whereas deterministic optimization problems are formulated with known parameters, real-world
problems almost invariably include some unknown parameters. To address this challenge, I
specifically formulate the scheduling problem as a two-stage stochastic program. In general, in a
two-stage stochastic program, the first stage variables are decided before the actual realization of
4
the uncertain parameters are known. Afterward, once the random events have exhibited themselves,
further decisions can be made by selecting the values of the second stage. The objective of the
SMILP above is to choose the optimal first stage variables in a way that the sum of first stage costs
and the expected value of the second stage or recourse costs is minimized. I then use the sample
average approximation (SAA) method [Ahmed et al., 2002; Pagnoncelli et al., 2009] to solve the
given SMILP. The main idea of the SAA approach to solve stochastic programs is to approximate
the expected value of the second stage cost by the weighted average function with the sample
realizations of the random vector that determines future meeting requests. The obtained sample
average approximation of the stochastic program is then solved using a standard branch and bound
algorithm such as those implemented in commercial integer programming solvers. For evaluation,
I compared the simulation results in energy savings achieved by the proposed predictive scheduling
algorithm against real-world data. These results show that my predictive scheduling algorithms
can potentially oer significant saving benefits in general scheduling domains where schedule
flexibility plays a key role for such savings.
The second contribution of my thesis provides a robust MDP (Markov Decision Problem)
model and algorithms to eectively reschedule group activities such as meetings/events for saving
energy while considering multiple objectives as well as uncertainty both at planning and execution
time [Kwak et al., 2012a,b]. In fact, in a complex domain, three challenges need to be considered.
First, there are inherently multiple competing objectives like limited energy supplies, and demands
to satisfy occupants’ comfort levels. This makes the problem harder as I need to explicitly consider
multi-objective optimization techniques. Second, as human occupants are directly involved in the
optimization procedures, understanding human behavior models and simultaneously reasoning
about such model uncertainty in the domain are essential. Third, while the oine policy is being
5
executed, there might be unexpected situations that were not captured at planning time. This
combination of challenges (multiple objectives and planning & execution-time uncertainty) has not
been considered in previous MDP algorithms [Chatterjee et al., 2006; Delgado et al., 2009; Givan
et al., 2000; Ogryczak et al., 2011]. Specifically, I present a novel model and robust algorithms:
BM-MDP (Bounded-parameter Multi-objective MDP) that explicitly models multiple objec-
tives as well as uncertainty over people’s preferences
robust algorithms to solve BM-MDPs and dynamic replanning methods for handling uncer-
tainty at execution time
BM-MDPs are a hybrid of MO-MDPs (Multi-Objective MDPs) Chatterjee et al. [2006];
Ogryczak et al. [2011] and BMDPs (Bounded-parameter MDPs) Givan et al. [2000]. Thus,
BM-MDPs are defined as an MDP where the reward function has been replaced by a vector
of rewards and upper and lower bounds on transition probabilities and rewards are provided as
closed real intervals. To optimally solve the given BM-MDPs, I provide algorithms based on
robust value iteration [Bagnell et al., 2001], which relies on a minimax approach, to obtain a
well-balanced solution across multiple objectives under model uncertainty. As I will show in the
results, BM-MDPs generate robust solutions while considering multiple objectives and model
uncertainty at planning time.
In practice, however, BM-MDPs may still not always capture unexpected situations that arise
while the BM-MDP policy is being executed. To handle such execution-time uncertainty, I also
provide the execution-centric replanning algorithms that heuristically replan the BM-MDP policy
while considering dynamic situations at execution time. As I will show in the evaluation section,
this replanning approach performs better than two other alternatives.
6
The final contribution of my thesis addresses fair division of credit using concepts of coopera-
tive game theory. When multiple users contribute to energy savings, fair division of credit for such
savings arises as an important question. Given the total amount of energy savings, what would
be a fair method to divide up credit of such energy savings? For instance, if each user were to
be compensated from a fixed portion of the entire group savings to incentivize further savings,
such equal division among all users would imply that those who made an extra eort get the same
credit as those who contributed little or nothing, which may not be perceived as fair [Nisan, 2007;
Nagarajan et al., 2010].
I appeal to cooperative game theory and specifically to the concept of Shapley value for this
fair division [Shapley, 1953]. While the Shapley value mathematically computes fair individual
allocations and holds desirable theoretical properties such as eciency, symmetry, linearity, etc.,
its limitation in scale is a major hindrance in practice [Nisan, 2007; Castro et al., 2009; Fatima et al.,
2008]. The Shapley value is based on the marginal contribution of each agent in a permutation, i.e.,
the amount of additional utility generated when that agent joins the coalition of her predecessors
in the permutation. And thus, the marginal contribution of each individual agent to every subset of
a given coalition should be considered. Furthermore, computing the marginal contribution in each
permutation (i.e., the characteristic function value) requires the exact computation of the energy
savings, which is computationally challenging. Thus, I provide a novel algorithmic contribution
for scaling up the overall computations:
approximation algorithms to eciently compute the Shapley value based on sampling and
partitions
an LP (linear program) relaxation method to speed up the characteristic function computation
7
Some studies suggest the use of sampling methods to approximate the Shapley value [Castro
et al., 2009]. Motivated by this prior work, I provide an approximate algorithm for the polynomial-
time calculation of the Shapley value based on sampling. An additional caching technique is used
to further speed-up the Shapley value computation by storing each evaluation of the characteristic
function. I also present the partition-based technique to decompose the entire agent set into smaller
independent subsets, which reduce the overall computational burden.
Next, in practice, the characteristic function computation itself is often computationally
intensive as it requires complex mathematical formulations (e.g., a mixed integer linear program
(MILP)) to be solved repeatedly. Thus, I present an LP relaxation method to speed up the
characteristic function computation by relaxing constraints of key integer decision variables. For
the corresponding LP relaxation to be practical, I also provide a rounding scheme for the resulting
continuous solution. As I will show in the evaluation section, these approximations allow ecient
computations of fair individual allocations in a large-scale saving game in the real-world. I
also show that dierent combinations of these approximations can be chosen under particular
circumstances while considering the tradeo between solution quality and runtime.
My algorithmic contributions discussed above have been successfully integrated within agents
dedicated to energy eciency. My thesis specifically introduces SA VES (Sustainable multi-Agent
building application for optimizingVarious objectives includingEnergy andSatisfaction) [Kwak
et al., 2012a,b], TESLA (Transformative Energy-saving Schedule-Leveraging Agent) [Kwak
et al., 2013a,b] and THINC (agentTool forHumanINcentivization andCooperation), illustrating
the potential for energy savings in commercial buildings. SA VES focuses on the day-to-day
energy-consumption of single individual or single group activity in commercial buildings, to be
reactive in suggesting energy conserving alternative to that individual or group. SA VES uses Ralph
8
& Goldy Lewis Hall (RGL) at the University of Southern California as a testbed building. More
specifically, SA VES provides the following key novelties:
jointly performed with the university facility management team, SA VES is based on actual
occupant preferences and schedules, actual energy consumption and loss data, real sensors
and hand-held devices, etc.
SA VES addresses novel scenarios that require agents to negotiate with groups of building
occupants to conserve energy; previous work has typically focused on agents’ negotiation
with individual occupants [Abras et al., 2008; Mo and Mahdavi, 2003].
SA VES focuses on non-residential buildings, which oer new opportunities for energy
conservation. In particular, since occupants may follow a more regular schedule, it allows
SA VES to plan ahead for energy conservation.
As mentioned previously, SA VES uses a novel algorithm for generating optimal BM-MDP
policies that explicitly considers multiple objective optimization (energy and personal
comfort) as well as uncertainty over occupant preferences when negotiating for energy
reduction.
Then, I provide three sets of evaluation results for SA VES. First, I constructed a detailed
simulation testbed, with details all the way down to individual electrical outlets in the targeted
building and variations in solar gain per day; and then validated this simulation. Within this
simulation testbed, I show that SA VES substantially reduces the overall energy consumption
compared to existing control methods while achieving comparable satisfaction level of occupants.
Second, I show the benefits of BM-MDPs by showing that it gives a well-balanced solution
9
while considering multiple objectives. Third, as a real-world test, I provide results of a human
subject study where SA VES is shown to lead human occupants to significantly reduce their energy
consumption in real buildings.
On the other hand, TESLA takes a long-range planning perspective and optimizes overall
energy consumption of a large number of group events or meetings together. TESLA is a goal-
seeking (to save energy), continuously running autonomous agent. Users in a commercial building
continuously submit meeting requests to TESLA while indicating flexibility in their meeting
preferences. TESLA schedules these meetings in the most energy ecient manner while ensuring
user comfort; but in cases where shifting meeting times can lead to significant savings, TESLA
interacts with users to request such a shift. More specifically, TESLA provides the following key
novelties:
As previously mentioned, TESLA presents online scheduling algorithms using the sample
average approximation (SAA) method to solve a two-stage stochastic mixed integer linear
program (SMILP). This SMILP considers the flexibility of people’s preferences for energy-
ecient scheduling of incrementally/dynamically arriving meetings and events.
TESLA also includes an algorithm to eectively identify key meetings that could lead
to significant energy savings by adjusting their flexibility while considering uncertainty
regarding people’s interactions.
For evaluation, I used a public domain simulation testbed [Kwak et al., 2012a,b], fitted it with
details of the testbed building, and compared the simulation results against real-world energy
usage data. TESLA was extensively evaluated on data gathered from over 110,000 meetings held
at nine campus buildings during an eight month period in 2011–2012 at the University of Southern
10
California (USC) and Singapore Management University (SMU), and an extensive analysis of the
energy saving results achieved by TESLA is provided. These analyses and results show that, in a
validated simulation using the testbed building, TESLA is projected to save about 94,000 kWh of
energy (roughly $18K) annually.
Lastly, THINC is the first agent integrating (i) energy-ecient scheduling of user meeting
requests while considering flexibility, (ii) rescheduling of key meetings for more energy savings,
and (iii) fair credit allocations based on Shapley value to incentivize users for their energy saving
activities (i.e., providing flexibility). More specifically, THINC provides the following key
novelties:
THINC computes fair division of credits from energy savings. For this fair division, THINC
uses novel algorithmic advances for ecient computation of Shapley value mentioned
earlier.
THINC includes a novel robust algorithm to optimally reschedule identified key meetings
addressing user interaction uncertainty.
For the evaluation, I built upon the simulation testbed by using a large data set of real meeting
requests and building statistics collected from the testbed building at USC. As a real-world test, I
actually deployed THINC at the Doheny library at USC in a limited fashion, collected real user’s
flexibility and their input, and demonstrated that THINC has significant potential to produce real
energy savings in commercial buildings.
11
1.3 Guide to Thesis
This thesis is organized in the following way. Chapter 2 introduces necessary background for
the research presented in this thesis. Chapter 3 presents robust algorithms for BM-MDPs, and
shows its extension to be applied in SA VES and the corresponding experimental results. Chapter 4
presents the robust optimization optimization framework for computing energy-ecient schedules
in TESLA and the corresponding experimental results. Chapter 5 describes THINC for handling
more realistic situations in order to be deployed in the real-world. Chapter 6 presents related work.
And finally, Chapter 7 concludes the thesis and presents issues for future work.
12
Chapter 2: Background
In this chapter, I provide a brief background regarding MDPs in Section 2.1, and discuss concepts
of cooperative game theory and specifically the Shapley value in Section 2.2. Next, I describe
two dierent sets of real testbed buildings in Section 2.3 and a simulation testbed in Section 2.4.
As a simulation environment is a main testbed to evaluate algorithms presented in my thesis, I
also provide the detailed evaluation results of the simulation environment using real building and
energy data in Section 2.4.3. Finally, in Section 2.5, I present a data analysis on massive number
of meeting requests collected from real testbed buildings described in Section 2.3.
2.1 Markov Decision Problems
Planning under uncertainty is fundamental to solving many important real-world problems, includ-
ing applications in robotics, network routing, scheduling, and financial decision making. Markov
Decision Problems (MDPs) [Puterman, 2009] provide a mathematical framework for modeling
these tasks and for deriving optimal solutions, which are described by a tuplehS; A; T; Ri:
S =fs
1
;:::; s
k
g is a finite set of states.
A is the finite set of actions of agent.
13
T : S A S7!R is the transition function, where T(s
0
js; a) is the transition probability
from s to s
0
if an action a is executed.
R : S A S 7! R is the reward function, where R(s; a; s
0
) is the reward agents get by
taking a from s and reaching s
0
.
The MDP is to obtain a policy with the highest expected reward/value and can be solved by
the following linear program (LP) formulation to find the optimal policy:
min V(s) (2.1)
s:t: V(s) R(s; a) +
X
s
0
2S
T(s; a; s
0
) V(s
0
); (2.2)
0
< 1 (2.3)
where V is a value function, and
is a discount factor.
2.2 Cooperative Game Theory and the Shapley Value
Cooperative game theory [Nisan, 2007; Leyton-Brown and Shoham, 2008] allows players to band
together and form coalitions. Formally, a cooperative game is defined by a pair (N; v), where
N =f1; 2;:::; ng is a set of players, and v is a characteristic function specifying the value created
of dierent subsets (i.e., coalitions) of the players in the game. Specifically, the characteristic
function, v(S ), associates with every subset S of N a value v(S ), the value of the coalition S .
In a cooperative game, we often want to encourage the grand coalition N to form. The
challenge is to allocate the overall payo v(N) among the players in a fair way so that they
14
will not deviate and form their own coalitions. Several solution concepts such as the Shapley
value [Shapley, 1953], the core [Gillies, 1959], and the nucleolus [Schmeidler, 1969] exist to guide
allocation. These solution concepts all find a vector x2R
N
that represents the allocation to each
player.
The Shapley value yields a unique allocation x(v) =(N; v) that is also fair. Specifically, the
Shapley value satisfies the eciency, symmetry, dummy player, and additivity properties which
axiomatize fairness. Other concepts in cooperative game theory such as the core and the nucleolus
focus on yielding stable outcomes, but not necessarily fairness, which is of key interest in our
work. Furthermore, the existence and uniqueness of the core are not guaranteed.
I use two (equivalent) definitions of Shapley value in our paper. The Shapley value is obtained
by averaging the marginal contributions over all possible coalitions. Specifically, the Shapley
value for player i is:
i
(N; v) =
n1
X
s=0
s!(n 1 s)!
n!
X
SNnfig;jSj=s
(v(S[fig) v(S )) (2.4)
where
i
(N; v) is the savings due to i2 N in the game (N; v).
An alternative definition of the Shapley value can be expressed in terms of all possible orders
of the players N. Let O :f1;:::; ng!f1;:::; ng be a permutation that assigns to each position
k the player O(k). Let us denote by(N) the set of all possible permutations with player set N.
Given a permutation O, let us denote by P
i
(O) the set of predecessors of the player i in the order O
15
(a) The actual testbed at USC for SA VES (b) The actual testbed buildings at USC and SMU for TESLA/THINC
Figure 2.1: Real Testbed Buildings
(i.e., P
i
(O) =fO(1);:::; O(k 1)g; if i = O(k)). Thus, the Shapley value can be expressed in the
following way:
i
(N; v) =
X
O2(N)
1
n!
(v(P
i
(O)[ i) v(P
i
(O))); i = 1;:::; n:
2.3 Educational Building Testbeds
Recall that my work focuses on two sets of agent-based systems: SA VES and TESLA.
2.3.1 The actual testbed building for SA VES
SA VES, focusing on multi-objective optimization under model uncertainty, is to be deployed in
an actual educational building (Ralph & Goldy Lewis Hall (RGL)) at the University of Southern
California (shown in Figure 2.1(a)). It is a multi-functional building that has been designed with a
building management system, and it provides a good environment to test various control strategies
to mitigate energy consumption. In particular, this campus building has three floors in total and
is composed of dierent types of spaces including classrooms, oces for faculty and sta, and
conference rooms for meetings. Each floor has a large number of rooms and zones (a set of
16
rooms that is controlled by specific piece of equipment) with various physical properties including
dierent building devices, orientation, window size, room size and lighting specifications.
Within this building, components and equipment include HV AC (Heating, Ventilating, and
Air Conditioning) systems, lighting systems, oce electronic devices such as computers and A V
equipment, and dierent types of sensors and energy meters. Human occupants of the building
are divided into two main categories: permanent and temporary. Permanent occupants include
oce users such as faculty, sta, researchers and laboratory residents. Temporary occupants
include scheduled occupants like students or faculty attending classes or meetings and unscheduled
occupants who are students or faculty using common lounges or dining spaces.
In this domain, there are two types of energy-related occupant behaviors that SA VES can
influence to conserve energy use: individual behaviors and group behaviors. Individual behaviors
only aect an environment where the individual is located. They include adjusting light sources
and temperature in individual oces and turning on/o computers and other electronics. Group
behaviors lead to changes in shared spaces and require negotiation with a group of occupants in
the building. For instance, SA VES may negotiate with a group of occupants to adjust the lighting
level and temperature in their shared oce or to relocate a meeting to a smaller oce. As I will
show later, energy savings by considering such group negotiations together are significant.
The desired goal in this educational building is to optimize multiple criteria, i.e., achieve
maximum energy savings without trading o the comfort level of occupants. The research on this
testbed building is intended to be generalized to other building types, where we can observe many
dierent types of energy-use and the behavioral patterns of occupants in the buildings.
17
Figure 2.2: The current room reservation system at the testbed building
2.3.2 The actual testbed buildings for TESLA & THINC
Figure 2.1(b) shows the testbed buildings for TESLA and THINC and the floor plans of 2
nd
and basement floors. They include one of main libraries (Leavey library) at USC and eight
educational buildings at Singapore Management University. They have been designed with a
building management system. Specifically, USC’s Leavey library hosts a large number of meetings
(about 300 unique meetings per regular day) across 35 group study rooms. Each study room has
dierent physical properties including dierent types and numbers of devices and facilities (e.g.,
video conferencing equipment, computer, projector, video recorder, oce electronic devices, etc.),
room size, lighting specification, and maximum capacity (4 – 15 people). This building operates
these study rooms 24 hours a day and 7 days a week except on national holidays. The temperature
in group study rooms is regulated by the facility managers according to two set ranges for occupied
and unoccupied periods of the day. HV AC systems always attempt to reach the pre-set temperature
regardless of the presence of people and their preferences in terms of temperature. Lighting and
appliance devices are manually controlled by users.
18
(a) (b)
Figure 2.3: Screen Capture of the Simulation Testbed
In this building, meetings are requested by users by a centralized online room reservation
system (see Figure 2.2). In the current reservation system, no underlying intelligent system is
used; instead, users reactively make a request based on the availability of room and time when they
access the system. While users make a request using the system, they are asked about additional
information including the number of meeting attendees and special requirements. Reservations
can be made up to 7 days in advance.
2.4 Simulation Testbed
As an important first step in deploying my work in the actual building described in the previous
section, I test my agent-based systems in a realistic simulation environment using real building
data. To that end, I have constructed a simulation testbed based on the open-source project
OpenSteer (http://opensteer.sourceforge.net/), which provides a 2D, OpenGL environment, as
shown in Figure 2.3. It can be used for ecient statistical analysis of dierent control strategies in
buildings before deploying the system.
19
2.4.1 Building Components
My simulation considers three building component categories: HV AC devices, lighting devices,
and appliances. The HV AC components control the temperature of the assigned zone. The lighting
devices control the lighting level of the room. The appliances in my simulation are either desktop
or laptop computers. These components have two possible actions: “on” and “standby”. When the
lighting or appliance devices are on, they consume a fixed amount of energy. My work attempts to
accurately reflect the energy consumed by each of the three component categories in the simulation.
The energy consumption of HV ACs is calculated based on changes in air temperature and airflow
speeds, and gains from natural light source and appliances in the space. To calculate the energy
consumption of the lighting and appliance devices, I collected actual energy consumption data in
the testbed building. For the appliances, a desktop computer spends 0.150 kW/h and 0.010 kW/h
when it is on and standby, respectively. A laptop computer spends 0.050 kW/h when it is on and
0.005 kW/h when it is on standby.
In the simulation testbed, the energy consumption (Q
z
) of HV AC is calculated as follow-
ing [Standard, 2001] mainly based on changes in air temperature and airflow speeds, and gains
from natural light source and appliances in the space, etc.:
20
Q
z
= Q
cw
+ Q
f an
; (2.5)
Q
cw
= 0:21 Q
cs
; (2.6)
Q
cs
= 1:1 (T
ma
T
sa
) V
sa
; (2.7)
T
ma
= (
V
bz
V
sa
) T
osa
+ (1 (
V
bz
V
sa
)) T
z
; (2.8)
Q
f an
= 1:25 3:412 V
sa
; (2.9)
V
sa
=
(W
sa
HC
da
H A) T + Q
zs
1:1 (T
z
T
sa
)
; (2.10)
V
bz
= max(20P; 0:05A); (2.11)
Q
zs
= (P 255) + (C 500) + (LW 3:412) + (0:5 A
zw
(T
osa
T
z
)) + (S G A
zw
);
(2.12)
In this work, I use measured parameter values such as solar gain (Figure 2.4(a)) and outdoor
temperature (Figure 2.4(b)) and real parameter values regarding the real testbed building (RGL) at
(a) Solar Gain (SG) (b) Outside Temperature (T
osa
) in April
Figure 2.4: Parameter Values for Energy Calculation
21
Table 2.1: Parameter Description for Energy Calculation
Parameters Meaning Default Value
A Zone Area (sq. ft)
A
zw
Window Area per Zone (sq. ft)
P Number of People in Zone
C Number of Computers in Current Use
LW Zone Light in Current Use (Watt)
T
z
Desired Temperature (
F)
T
sa
Temperature of Supply Air (
F) 60.0
F
T
osa
Temperature of Outside Air
S G Solar Gain
W
sa
Specific Weight of Air (lb/ft
3
) 0.07495 lb/ft
3
HC
da
Heat Capacity Dry Air (BTU/lbF) 0.24 BTU/lbF
H Ceiling Height (ft) 10.0 ft
T Temperature change (
F/hr)
Figure 2.5: RGL Floor Plan (2
nd
& 3
rd
floors of the testbed building)
the University of Southern California (Figure 2.5) obtained from the facility management system.
Specifically, Tables 2.1 & 2.2 show the parameter values I used for the above energy calculation.
22
Table 2.2: Parameter Values for Energy Calculation
Zone LW (kWh) A (sqft) A
zw
(sqft)
1 0.384 260 44.8
2 0.48 352 87.2
3 0.544 332 64.8
4 0.432 349 64.8
5 0.192 138 44.8
6 0.576 414 64.8
7 0.384 274 64.8
8 0.384 274 64.8
9 0.192 163 44.8
10 0.448 320 0.0
11 0.192 136 44.8
12 0.192 115 44.8
13 0.288 236 44.8
14 0.576 497 79.1
15 0.288 197 44.8
16 0.384 260 44.8
17 0.192 125 0.0
18 0.87 313 79.1
19 2.256 669 135.8
20 0.464 435 0.0
21 0.786 298 22.4
22 0.576 411 67.2
23 0.576 411 44.8
24 3.22 1318 0.0
2.4.2 Human Occupants
I built two types of human occupants in my simulation using the agent behavior framework.
Permanent occupants stay in their oces or follow their regular schedules. Temporary occupants
stay in the building for classes and leave once classes end.
Each occupant has access to a subset of the six available behaviors according to her/his type —
wander, attend class, go to meeting, teach, study, and perform research — any one of which may
be active at a given time, where the behavior is selected based on class and meeting schedules.
23
Figure 2.6: Actual Temperature Preference
Occupants also have a satisfaction level based on the current environment, modeled as a percentage
between 0 and 100 (0 is fully dissatisfied, 100 is fully satisfied).
To model the satisfaction level in this simulation, I use a Gaussian distribution N(;) for each
occupant. The mean () of each individual Gaussian is drawn from actual occupant preference data
shown in Figure 2.6 (e.g., for 18% of permanent occupants,=76
F). This data was gathered from
40 permanent occupants and 202 temporary occupants in RGL over two weeks in the spring of
2011. I use this actual data instead of the ASHRAE standard, which fails to account for individual
preferences. The standard deviation () of each Gaussian is selected uniformly randomly from a
range of 3–5
F [Khalifa et al., 2006]. Based on the constructed Gaussian model for each occupant,
the satisfaction level is computed as follows:
S (t) =
8
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
:
100; if t =
f (t)
f ()
100; if t,
(2.13)
24
Figure 2.7: Energy Consumption Validation
where S (t) is the satisfaction function, f (x) is the probability density function of N(;), and t is
the current temperature.
2.4.3 Validation
Before testing agents including SA VES, TESLA and THINC in simulation, I validate the simulation
testbed. Specifically, I first compare the energy consumption calculated in the simulation testbed
with actual energy meter data using the 3
rd
floor of the actual testbed building (RGL).
Figure 2.7 shows that daily energy use comparison data (y-axis) measured for 30 sample
weekdays throughout dierent seasons (x-axis; 3 weekdays in 2011 Spring, 10 weekdays in 2011
Summer, 17 weekdays in 2011 Fall). The energy consumption includes the amount consumed by
HV ACs, lighting devices and appliances. My work uses measured parameter values such as solar
gain and outdoor temperature and real parameter values for the building obtained from the facility
management system. I set the starting indoor temperature using real data. The likelihood value for
25
Table 2.3: Energy consumption validation (kWh)
H
H
H
H
H
H
Period
Regular semester (Spring/Fall) Summer break Average
Actual energy consumption 740.2 289.6 546.7
Simulated energy consumption 721.3 255.1 521.1
Average error (%) 2.6 11.9 4.7
human occupants to “turn o” lights and appliances when they leave their oces is 76%, based
on a survey of the testbed building. Students follow 2010 Fall, 2011 Spring and 2011 Fall class
schedules, and faculty, sta and students follow their meeting schedules.
As shown in the figure, the dierence between actual energy meter data and energy use from
the simulation testbed was between 0.17% – 8.71% (mean dierence: 3.37%), which strongly
supports my claim that the simulation testbed is realistic.
To evaluate TESLA and THINC, I then compared the energy consumption calculated in
the simulation testbed with actual energy meter data from the testbed building (library) at the
University of Southern California in 2012. As shown in Table 2.3, the average dierence between
actual energy meter data and energy use from the simulation testbed was 4.7%, which strongly
supports my claim that the simulation testbed is realistic. This validated simulation environment is
used to evaluate TESLA and THINC with real meeting data. In addition, I also test TESLA on
buildings at Singapore Management University. SMU has a centralized web-based system that
allows users to schedule meetings and events in over 500 conference/meeting rooms across eight
buildings. More details regarding the data sets from USC and SMU to test TESLA and THINC
are provided in the next section.
26
(a) Meeting frequency data (b) Distribution of total meeting requests per day
Figure 2.8: Real data analysis (USC)
Table 2.4: Meeting request arrival distribution
Time period Likelihood (%)
1 day before 55.73
1-2 days before 18.40
2-3 days 8.72
3-4 days 5.52
4-5 days 3.68
5-6 days 3.05
6-7 days 3.35
> 7 days 1.56
2.5 Data Analysis
In collaboration with building system managers, I have been collecting data specifying the past
usage of group study rooms, which are collected for 8 months (January through August in 2012) at
USC. The data for each meeting request includes the time of request, starting time, time duration,
specified room, and group size. The data set contains 32,065 unique meetings, and their average
meeting time duration is 1.78 hours.
Figure 2.8(a) shows the actual meeting frequency (y-axis) over time (24 hours, x-axis) of
sampled 4 locations at USC (out of 35 rooms) based on the collected meeting request data. This
27
(a) Meeting frequency data (b) Distribution of total meeting requests per day
Figure 2.9: Real data analysis (SMU)
figure shows the preferred slots of time and location (e.g., late afternoon (2–5pm) for time & 2
nd
floor (201A, 202E) compared to the basement for location). Then, the system will be able to
predict future situations based on this frequency data while scheduling requests as they arrive.
Figure 2.8(b) shows the probability distribution over total meeting requests per day. The x-axis of
the figure indicates the total number of meeting requests per day (ranging from 0 to about 350)
and the y-axis shows how likely the system will have the given number of total meeting requests
(x-axis) on one day. One can see that the probability of having 50 or fewer meetings is 42.92%
and the probability of having 250 or more meetings is 30.04%. These are used to estimate the
model of future meetings in my scheduling algorithm that will be presented in Chapter 4.
Table 2.4 shows how early meeting requests were made. In the table, column 2 indicates the
percentage of meetings that were requested within the given time period (column 1). For instance,
55.73% of all meeting requests were made within 1 day before the actual meeting day. This
analysis would be helpful in understanding how my algorithm could achieve significant energy
savings in this domain.
28
While evaluating my work, I also consider another data set from SMU. The data set contains
over 80,000 meetings that have been collected for three months (August through October) in
2011 at SMU, which gives a sense regarding how my algorithm will handle energy-oriented
scheduling problems in large buildings. Similar to Figure 2.8, Figure 2.9(a) shows the actual
meeting frequency (y-axis) over time (24 hours, x-axis) of sampled 4 locations at SMU (out of
over 500 rooms) based on the collected meeting request data. This figure shows the preferred slots
of time and location. Figure 2.9(b) shows the probability distribution over total meeting requests
per day. The x-axis of the figure indicates the total number of meeting requests per day (ranging
from 0 to about 1200) and the y-axis shows how likely the system will have the given number of
total meeting requests (x-axis) on one day.
29
Chapter 3: SA VES
In this chapter, I first describe the key components of SA VES and how to optimally plan negotia-
tions with groups of occupants to conserve energy in the real-world application.
3.1 Agents in SA VES
At the heart of SA VES are two types of agents: room agents and proxy agents (Figure 3.1).
There is a dedicated room agent per oce and conference room, in charge of reducing energy
Figure 3.1: Agents & Communication Equipment in SA VES. An agent in SA VES sends feedback
including energy use to occupants.
30
consumption in that room. It can access sensors to retrieve information such as the current lighting
level and temperature and energy use at dierent levels (building-level, floor-level, zone-level, and
room-level) and impact the operation of actuators. A proxy agent [Scerri et al., 2002] is on an
individual occupant’s hand-held device and it has the corresponding occupant’s preference and
behavior models. Proxy agents communicate on behalf of an occupant to the room agent. Such
proxy agents’ adjustable autonomy – when to interrupt a user and when to act autonomously – is
recognized as a major research issue [Scerri et al., 2002; Schurr et al., 2009], but since it is not my
focus, I use preset rules instead. Room agents may directly communicate with occupants without
proxy agents if needed. Finally, dierent room agents coordinate among themselves via proxy
agents, e.g., if two separate conference room agents wish to move a meeting to one occupant’s
oce, the proxy of that occupant allows one of the room agents to proceed, blocking the other’s
request (see Figure 3.1).
Room agent reasoning is based on a new model called Bounded parameter Multi-objective
MDPs (BM-MDPs), which is one of the contributions of this research. BM-MDPs are a hybrid
of MO-MDPs [Chatterjee et al., 2006; Ogryczak et al., 2011] and BMDPs [Givan et al., 2000].
BM-MDPs are responsible for planning simple and complex tasks. Simple tasks include turning on
the HV AC before a class or a meeting, and do not need the full power of the BM-MDPs. Complex
tasks were why BM-MDPs were created; these include negotiating with groups of individuals
to relocate meetings to smaller rooms to save energy, negotiating with multiple occupants of a
shared oce to reduce energy usage in the form of lights or HV ACs, and others. Before describing
BM-MDPs in depth, I motivate their use by elaborating on the meeting relocation negotiation
scenario.
31
Group Meeting Relocation Negotiation Example Consider a meeting that has been scheduled
with two attendees (P
1
and P
2
) in a large conference room that has more light sources and
appliances than smaller oces. Since the meeting has few attendees, the room agent can negotiate
with attendees to relocate the meeting to nearby small, sunlit oces, which can lead to significant
energy savings. The room agent handles this negotiation based on BM-MDPs. There are three
objectives (i.e., three separate reward functions) that the room agent needs to consider during this
negotiation: (i) energy saving (R
1
), (ii) P
1
’s comfort level change (R
2
), and (iii) P
2
’s comfort level
change (R
3
). The room agent first checks the available oces. Assuming there are two available
oces A and B, the room agent asks each attendee if she or he will agree to relocate the meeting
to one of the available oces. In asking an attendee, the room agent must consider the uncertainty
of whether an attendee is likely to accept its oer to relocate the meeting. Since asking incurs
a cost (e.g., cost caused by interrupting people), the room agent needs to reason about which
option is preferable considering P
1
and P
2
’s likelihood to accept each option (A or B) and the
reward functions for each option to reduce the required cost and maximize benefits. Assuming
A is preferable, the optimal policy of the agent is “ask P
1
first about A”–“if P
1
accepts, ask P
2
about A”–“if P
1
does not reply, ask P
1
about A again”–“repeat the process with B”–“if both agree,
relocate the meeting”–“if both disagree, find other available options.” While this is a simplified
example, in practice the problem is more dicult, as there may be more than two attendees in a
meeting. The room agent must also first communicate with the proxies of the owners of oces A
and B and there may be uncertainty in their agreement to have a meeting in their oce; further
adding to the challenge of sequential decision making under uncertainty. In addition, the agent
must decide if it should ask P
1
first and use that result to influence P
2
, etc.
32
Thus, BM-MDPs must reason with multiple objectives, but simultaneously must reason with
the uncertainty in the domain. In fact, in a complex domain such as mine, the probabilities of
attendees’ or others’ acceptance of the room agent’s oer, or the probabilities of other outcomes
may not be precisely known — we may only have a reasonable upper and lower bound over such
probabilities. Indeed, precisely knowing the model is very challenging, and I ended up building
BM-MDPs to address both these challenges and requirements. However, before explaining
BM-MDPs, I first explain MO-MDPs on which BM-MDPs are built.
3.2 Multi-objective MDPs
The negotiation scenarios described earlier require SA VES to consider multiple objectives simul-
taneously: energy consumption and satisfaction level of multiple individuals. To handle such
multiple objectives, MDPs have been extended to take into account multiple criteria assuming
no model uncertainty. Multi-Objective MDPs (MO-MDPs) [Chatterjee et al., 2006; Ogryczak
et al., 2011] are defined as an MDP where the reward function has been replaced by a vector of
rewards. Specifically, MO-MDPs are described by a tuplehS; A; T;fR
i
g; pi, where R
i
is the reward
function for objective i and p denotes the starting state distribution (p(s) 0). In the meeting
relocation example shown in Section 3.1, specifically, the multiple reward functions,fR
i
g, include
energy consumption (which is the reduction in energy usage in moving from a conference room to
a smaller oce), and comfort level defined separately for each individual (based on data related to
their temperature comfort zones).
The key takeaway from MO-MDPs towards BM-MDPs is an understanding of how to generate
a policy in the presence of such multiple objectives that are not aggregated into one single value.
33
The key principle I rely on, given the current domain of non-residential buildings is one of fairness;
we wish to reduce energy usage, but we cannot sacrifice any one individual’s comfort entirely in
service of this goal. To meet this requirement, I focus on minimizing the maximum regret instead
of maximizing the reward value based on a min-max optimization technique [Osyczka, 1978] to
get a well-balanced solution.
To minimize the maximum regret, I first need to compute the optimal value for each objective
using the MDP framework relying on the following standard formulation:
min V
(s) (3.1)
s:t: V
(s) R(s; a) +
X
s
0
2S
T(s; a; s
0
) V
(s
0
); (3.2)
0
< 1 (3.3)
where V
is an optimal value, and
is a discount factor.
I define the regret in MO-MDPs as following:
Definition 1. Let H
i
(s) be the regret with respect to a policy for objective i and state s. Formally,
H
i
(s) = V
i
i
(s) V
i
(s); (3.4)
where V
i
i
(s) is the value of the optimal policy,
i
, and V
i
(s) is the value of the policy for
objective i and state s.
Therefore, I can minimize the maximum regret in MO-MDPs using the following optimization
problem:
34
min D (3.5)
s:t: D
X
s2S
p(s)
h
V
i
(s) V
i
(s)
i
;8i2 I; (3.6)
V
i
(s) =
X
a2A
(s; a)
2
6
6
6
6
6
4
R
i
(s; a) +
X
s
0
2S
T(s; a; s
0
) V
i
(s
0
)
3
7
7
7
7
7
5
; (3.7)
X
a2A
(s; a) = 1;8s2 S; 0
< 1 (3.8)
where V
i
is the constant value pre-calculated by (2) of the MDP formulation using the reward
function for objective i, R
i
, and I is a set of objectives.
Unfortunately, in BM-MDPs, I have an upper and lower bound on transition probabilities and
rewards, and thus this optimization problem cannot be directly used. Nonetheless, it helps us
understand the key dierence in minimizing max regret between MO-MDPs and BM-MDPs —
specifically in addressing such upper and lower bounds in BM-MDPs, we end up with dierent
transition probabilities T
i
for each objective i, as discussed below, and hence rely on a dierent
approach to compute regret.
3.3 BM-MDPs
I now extend MO-MDPs, using ideas from BMDPs [Givan et al., 2000], to create BM-MDPs.
BMDP (represented by tuplehS; A;
ˆ
T;
ˆ
R; pi) is an extension to the standard MDP, where upper
and lower bounds on transition probabilities and rewards are provided as closed real intervals. In
addition to representation of uncertainty over transition probabilities and rewards, a key takeaway
for BM-MDPs from BMDPs is the algorithm to generate policies. This algorithm is based on the
35
notion of Order-Maximizing MDPs [Givan et al., 2000], which selects transition probabilities from
the given intervals. Order-maximizing MDPs crucially take the order of states as an input – this
order is ascending for a pessimistic policy (based on lower bound values), and it is descending
for an optimistic policy (based on upper bound values). More specifically, using this order as an
input, order-maximizing MDPs construct the transition function, and generate a policy as an output
relying on value iteration. I rely on order-maximizing MDPs to generate policies in BM-MDPs as
well (but manipulate the order of states input). To provide some intuition behind the operations
of the order-maximizing MDPs, I provide a simple example to show how transition values are
assigned from their intervals using the given order in the following example. For more details,
please refer to [Givan et al., 2000].
Example of Order Maximizing MDPs Consider a BMDP with two states: s
1
and s
2
. The
transition ranges are T(s
1
; a; s
1
) = [0.5, 0.9], T(s
1
; a; s
2
) = [0.2, 0.6]. Let us assume that the upper
bound of value is V
ub
(s
1
) = 3 and V
ub
(s
2
) = 2 at a certain iteration of order-maximizing MDP value
iteration. In BMDP, the intuition is that for calculating the optimistic value, it requires movement
to s
1
as much as possible within the given range of transition probability (since it has a higher
upper bound value). Therefore to create an optimistic policy, the input to the order-maximizing
MDPs is to sort the states in a descending order based on the upper bounds. Given this input, the
transition probabilities in the order-maximizing MDP for calculating optimistic value would be
T
0
(s
1
; a; s
1
) = 0.8 because T
0
(s
1
; a; s
2
) should be at least 0.2, and T
0
(s
1
; a; s
2
) = (1 - 0.8). Based
on these transition probabilities, I obtain a new set of expected values via value iteration, generate
a new descending order, and iterate until convergence.
36
Similar to BMDPs, the transition and reward functions in BM-MDPs have closed real intervals.
Whereas BMDPs are limited to optimizing a single objective case (i.e., the BMDP model requires
one unified reward function), BM-MDPs can (i) optimize over multiple objectives (i.e., a vector of
reward functions) with (ii) dierent degrees of model uncertainty. Specifically, BM-MDPs are
described by a tuplehS; A;
ˆ
T;f
ˆ
R
i
g; pi, where
ˆ
R
i
represents the reward function for objective i.
Algorithm 1 SolveBMMDP()
1: for i = 12 I do
2:
D
V
i;lb
; V
i;ub
E
SolveBMDP(BMDP
i
)
3: fV
0
i;lb
g 1 ;fV
i;lb
g 0
4: whilejfV
0
i;lb
gfV
i;lb
gj> do
5: fV
i;lb
g fV
0
i;lb
g
6: for i = 12 I do
7: O
i
SortIncreasingOrder(fV
i;lb
g)
8: M
i
ConstructOrderMaximizingMDP(O
i
);
9: fV
0
i;lb
g SolveMOMDPPessimistic(fV
i;lb
g;fV
i;lb
g;fM
i
g)
10:
pes
ObtainPessimisticPolicy(fV
i;lb
g)
11: fV
0
i;ub
g 1 ;fV
i;ub
g 0
12: whilejfV
0
i;ub
gfV
i;ub
gj> do
13: fV
i;ub
g fV
0
i;ub
g
14: for i = 12 I do
15: O
i
SortDecreasingOrder(fV
i;ub
g)
16: M
i
ConstructOrderMaximizingMDP(O
i
);
17: fV
0
i;ub
g SolveMOMDPOptimistic(fV
i;ub
g;fV
i;ub
g;fM
i
g)
18:
opt
ObtainOptimisticPolicy(fV
i;ub
g)
19: return f
D
pes
;
opt
E
g
To solve BM-MDPs, I introduce a novel algorithm that is a hybrid of BMDPs and MO-MDPs.
Specifically, my algorithm marries the minimization of max regret idea from MO-MDPs with
that of order maximizing MDPs to handle uncertainty over transition function and rewards. The
overall flow is described in Algorithm 1. At a higher level, there are three stages: (i) computing
the optimal value bounds
D
V
i;lb
; V
i;ub
E
for each objective i using BMDPs (lines 1–2), (ii) using
the MO-MDP idea to optimize multiple objectives based on a min-max formulation (lines 3–9 &
11–17), and (iii) obtaining a policy based on the final value functions
fV
i;lb
g;fV
i;ub
g
(lines 10
37
& 18). The output of this algorithm is in the form of two policies (pessimistic and optimistic), and
I leave it to the user to determine which one is used.
I now describe the computation of the pessimistic policy (lines 3–10). The optimistic policy
(lines 11–18) is similarly computed. The pessimistic policy minimizes the maximum regret with
respect to the optimal lower bound values of all objectives (fV
i;lb
g) over all states; this computation
is iteratively performed in line 9. For each objective i, I first get an ascending order of states using
the current lower bound values V
i;lb
(line 7) to construct the order-maximizing MDP (line 8). This
set of order-maximizing MDPs,fM
i
g, is an input to the function SolveMOMDPPessimistic() to
optimize multiple objectives by directly computing regret on line 9. This computation is performed
by Eq. (3.5) with a dierent transition probability function T
i
in the given M
i
instead of T. This
in turn influences the sorting order of states, and the process continues until the expected values
fV
i;lb
g converge.
3.4 Evaluation of SA VES
In this section, I provide three sets of evaluations: two sets of results tested in the simulation
testbed and a set of results tested in the real-world.
3.4.1 Simulation: Overall Evaluation
I evaluate the performance of SA VES using both 2
nd
and 3
rd
floors of RGL in the simulation
environment. I test BM-MDPs using a pessimistic setting and compare it with two other control
heuristics discussed below.
38
Manual Control: The manual control strategy is the baseline system that represents the current
strategy operated by the facility management team in the real testbed building (RGL). In this
strategy, temperature is regulated by the facility managers according to two set ranges for occupied
(70
F–75
F) and unoccupied periods (50
F–90
F) of the day. In this control setting, HV ACs
always attempt to reach the pre-set temperature regardless of the presence of occupants and their
preferences in terms of temperature. Lighting and appliance devices are controlled by human
occupants. The same likelihood value for human occupants to “turn o” lights and appliances was
used as in Section 2.4.
Reactive Control: I consider the reactive control heuristic for comparison purposes since it can
be easily implemented using cheap sensors in the real building, and recently, some buildings have
already started adopting this simple heuristic to reduce energy use. The lighting and appliance
devices are now automatically controlled and turned on and o according to the presence of
people. Additionally, as in [Jazizadeh et al., 2011], appropriate temperature set points of HV ACs
are computed based on the average preference of human occupants. HV ACs automatically turn on
and o according to the presence of people and temperature set points.
I focus on measuring two dierent criteria — total energy consumption (kWh) and average
satisfaction level of occupants (%). The experiments were run on Intel Core2 Duo 2.53GHz CPU
with 4GB main memory. All techniques were evaluated for 100 independent trials throughout this
section. I report the average values.
3.4.1.1 Result: Total Energy Consumption
I compared the cumulative total energy consumption measured during 24 hours for all control
strategies. Figure 3.2(a) shows the cumulative total energy consumption on the y-axis in kWh
39
(a) Total Energy Consumption (b) Average Satisfaction Level
Figure 3.2: Performance Evaluation of SA VES
and time on the x-axis. I report the average total energy consumption measured over the same 30
weekdays used in Figure 2.7. As shown in the figure, the manual control strategy showed the worst
result since it does not take into account behaviors or schedules of human occupants and building
components simply follow the predefined policies. The reactive control strategies showed lower
energy consumption than the manual setting by 16.06%. SA VES showed the best results compared
to other control heuristics and statistically significant improvements (t-test; p< 0:01) in terms of
energy used in the testbed building. Specifically, my algorithm with the ideal compliance rate (i.e.,
SA VES-IDEAL: occupants always accept the suggestions provided by the SA VES room agents
to conserve energy) reduced the energy consumption by 42.45% when compared to the manual
control strategy. If I use the compliance rate (68.18%) of human subjects shown in Table 3.3 (as
measured in the real-world experiments), SA VES achieved energy savings by 31.27% (40% of the
savings due to SA VES came out of group tasks, such as reducing energy consumption in shared
oces, relocating meetings, and others) as compared to the manual setup. This is double the rate
of the reactive approach.
40
3.4.1.2 Result: Average Satisfaction Level
Here, I compare the average satisfaction level of human occupants under dierent control strategies
in the simulation testbed. Figure 3.2(b) shows the average satisfaction level in percentage on
the y-axis and time on the x-axis. As shown in the results, the manual setting and my novel
algorithm showed the best results. This is because the manual setting makes HV ACs attempt to
reach the desired temperature set point as soon as possible while disregarding the resulting energy
consumption, and my method plans ahead of the schedules; thus, these two can achieve the desired
comfort level faster than the reactive control strategy.
The manual strategy, however, is very sensitive to the given temperature range. In the experi-
ment, the temperature set point was set by the facility management team (e.g., 70–75
F) based
on the average preference model, thus it achieved high comfort level in the testbed. However, if
the actual preferred temperature in the building is dierent from the average model, it fails to
meet the occupant’s desired level. This phenomenon can be seen when occupants stay during the
unoccupied time (after typical working hours). As can be seen at 18 on the x-axis (i.e., 6pm) in
the figure, the average comfort level drops significantly. Due to the delayed eects in temperature
change, the reactive control strategy showed significantly lower satisfaction results than other
methods. For instance, it has a satisfaction level below 60% at 14 on the x-axis (i.e., 2pm). Thus,
SA VES not only provides superior energy savings, but also avoids the reduction in comfort level
that a reactive strategy may cause.
3.4.2 Simulation: Multi-objective Optimization
In this section, I perform more analysis on my novel algorithm. Table 3.1 shows the average
maximum regret comparison tested in 5 dierent problem sets between the standard MDP with
41
Table 3.1: Average Maximum Regret Comparison
Problem Set MDPs BM-MDPs Dierence
m
1
168.62 4.72 163.90
m
2
359.44 164.17 195.27
m
3
448.15 164.97 283.18
m
4
291.27 138.59 152.68
m
5
143.32 95.88 47.44
Table 3.2: Example of the Meeting Relocation Negotiation
Max. Regret
Objective MDPs BM-MDPs
Energy Savings 443.54 162.83
P
1
’s Comfort Lv. Change 15.34 162.84
P
2
’s Comfort Lv. Change 15.34 97.58
a unified reward based on the weighted sum method [Yoon and Hwang, 1995] and BM-MDPs
(in this case, I assume no transition or reward uncertainty). The uniform weight distribution was
applied to the weighted sum method. My goal is to show that BM-MDPs give lower maximum
regrets, which indicates well-balanced solutions as discussed earlier.
Each problem is an instance of the meeting relocation negotiation task, having its own reward
structure but the same transition function. The problem instances are divided into five groups
(problem sets m
1
–m
5
) based on the percentage of objectives that have positive rewards in all
objectives. Recall that in the meeting relocation scenario, the dierent objectives include energy
reduction and change in comfort level of individual participants. Specifically, in problem set m
1
,
relocating a meeting leads to positive rewards in over 75% of objectives (76–100%) and negative
rewards in the rest of objectives, problem set m
2
has 51–75% of objectives with positive rewards,
and similarly for the remaining sets, so that in problem set m
5
, all objectives have negative rewards
if the meeting is relocated. Each problem set has 100 independent problem instances. I then
measured the average maximum regret of each method in each problem set. As shown in Table 3.1,
42
BM-MDPs always showed lower maximum regrets (column 3) compared to the MDP with uniform
weight (column 2), which suggests that my method gives well-balanced solutions regardless of
reward characteristics.
The next question is what the well-balanced solution means in energy domains. Let us take the
meeting relocation example with two attendees (P
1
and P
2
) discussed in Section 3.1. In Table 3.2,
column 1 shows three objectives (energy savings and two attendees’ comfort level change) and
columns 2–3 indicate the maximum regret from MDPs and BM-MDPs, respectively. As shown
in the table, MDPs generated a policy that almost entirely disregards energy-savings, leading to
significantly large regrets (row 3, column 2). BM-MDPs, on the other hand, were able to achieve
small regrets over all objectives (rows 3–5, column 3).
Lastly, I test my BM-MDP algorithm considering dierent degrees of model uncertainty.
Figure 3.3 shows the average maximum regret tested over 100 dierent problem instances on the
y-axis. I choose 1 problem from each problem set (m
1
, m
2
, , m
5
) from the previous test. The
noise of each model is proportional (20%) to the mean reward value and transition probability.
MDPs and MO-MDPs generate policies ignoring the model’s uncertainty and BM-MDPs generate
two types of policies (BM-MDP-Pes: pessimistic, BM-MDP-Opt: optimistic) that explicitly
account for the uncertainty. I then randomly generate 20 dierent instances within the range for
each problem (e.g., for m
1
, I generate m
1;1
, , m
1;20
). Each generated policy is evaluated over
those 20 problem instances and the average maximum regret is computed for each algorithm.
For the other 4 problems (m
2
, , m
5
), I repeat the same procedure and report the overall
average value. As shown in the figure, BM-MDPs have the best performance (i.e., lowest average
maximum regret), which means BM-MDPs are capable of generating more robust and well-
balanced solutions compared to previous work when there is model uncertainty. However, the
43
Figure 3.3: Performance of BM-MDPs
solution quality between the pessimistic and optimistic BM-MDPs was not significantly dierent
and their performance is domain dependent. Note that the results shown in Figure 3.3 are average
maximum regrets over all problem instances, and in some particular instances, MO-MDP might
outperform either BM-MDP-Pes or BM-MDP-Opt (but not both even in this case). I leave this
issue for future investigation.
3.4.3 Real-world Test: Human Experiments
As a real-world test, I design and conduct a validation experiment on a pilot sample of participants
(sta on campus). I conduct this investigation: (i) to verify if SA VES can lead to changes in
occupants’ behaviors and to reduce energy consumption in commercial buildings, (ii) to validate
the parameter values used during the negotiation process such as the acceptance/compliance rate
for the suggestion and (iii) to understand what types of feedback are most eective to aect
occupants’ energy-related decisions.
44
In this study, I consider two test conditions: (i) feedback without motivation (Test Group I)
(e.g., please reduce the lighting level in your oce), and (ii) feedback with motivation including
participant’s own energy use, and environmental motives (Test Group II) (e.g., if you reduce your
lighting for working hours, the annual energy savings at the building level are 26000kWh on
average, which is equivalent to the reduction of CO
2
emissions of 2.2 homes for one year). From
this experiment, I answer the following question by comparing change in energy behavior patterns
and possible estimated energy consumption between test groups I and II.
Hypothesis 1. More informed feedback (provided to subjects in Test Group II) will be more
eective to conserve energy than feedback without motivation (Test Group I).
I tested the hypothesis above as follows: I first recruited 22 sta from 7 buildings at the
University of Southern California who are over 18 years old. Subjects were tested under two
dierent conditions, and each test group had 11 individuals respectively, each of whom has her/his
own oce. Since I tested using a simple lighting negotiation scenario, each participant must
be able to adjust the lighting levels in her/his oce. With participants’ agreements, I installed
lighting sensors (Figure 3.1) in their oces. During the experiment, participants were supposed to
stay in their own oces and do their regular work. I then measured the baseline energy behavior
and energy consumption, and SA VES provided feedback via emails based on sensed lighting
level (two times per day, at 11am and 2pm, for three consecutive weekdays). In each message,
participants received a simple suggestion for lighting level with a certain type of feedback (e.g.,
please reduce the lighting level in your oce). I systematically observed and logged their energy
behavior during the entire experiment using the light sensors. At the end of the experiment, each
participant was required to take a short survey (i.e., the reasons why they agree or disagree with a
45
Table 3.3: Lighting Negotiation Results (*: p< 0.05)
Avg. Accep. Rate (%) User Rating (Max: 5.0)
Group I 28.79 (11.03) 3.82 (0.26)
Group II 68.18 (9.65) 4.18 (0.18)
Mean Di. 39.39
0.36
provided suggestion). I conducted this study for two weeks in the fall of 2011 and collected data
from human subjects using multiple sensors and routers.
In Table 3.3, column 2 displays the average acceptance rate in percentage (0–100%) of two
test groups, and column 3 represents the average user rating of the provided feedback during the
experiment. The range of ratings is between 0 and 5, and 0 indicates that the feedback was not
helpful at all, and 5 means that the feedback was extremely helpful. In both columns, values
in parentheses indicate the standard errors. The last row shows a mean dierence between two
groups for each value.
Table 3.3 shows that when I provided more informed feedback including environmental
motives (Group II), occupants showed statistically significantly higher compliance acceptance rate
(68.18%), which provides strong evidence for the above hypothesis (t-test; p< 0:05). In addition,
human subjects in Group II felt that the provided feedback was more helpful during the negotiation
process. However, the dierence in user ratings between two groups was not significant, and
thus I took a quick survey from participants at the end of the experiment to further analyze their
decisions. In contrast with Group I, in Group II, the main reason why participants who agreed
to reduce the lighting level in their oces (over 80% of conformers in Group II) was because
the feedback significantly improved awareness of energy use. In addition, more than half of all
participants strongly believed that this study will be very helpful by encouraging occupants to
46
think about energy usage. This discrepancy in average user ratings and acceptance rates remains
an issue for future work.
In this trial study, I have learned that although occupants in commercial buildings do not have
a direct financial incentive in saving energy, proper motivations can achieve a higher compliance
rate for the energy-related suggestion. This study specifically provides the insights that there is a
significant potential to conserve energy by investigating eective and tailored methods to improve
occupants’ motivation to conserve energy.
47
Chapter 4: TESLA
In this chapter, I describe the overall architecture of TESLA and how to optimally schedule
meetings in real-world situations to conserve energy in commercial buildings.
4.1 TESLA Architecture
TESLA is a goal-seeking (to save energy), continuously running autonomous agent. TESLA
performs on-line energy-ecient scheduling while considering dynamically arriving inputs from
Figure 4.1: TESLA architecture: TESLA is a continuously running agent that supports four key
features: (i) energy-ecient scheduling; (ii) identification of key meetings; (iii) learning of user
preferences; and (iv) communication with users.
48
users; these dynamic inputs make the scheduling complex and TESLA needs to learn a predictive
model for users’ inputs and preferences (see Figure 4.1). More specifically, TESLA :
takes inputs (i.e., preferred time, location, the number of meeting attendees, etc.) from
dierent users and their proxy agents at dierent times
autonomously performs on-line energy-ecient scheduling as requests arrive while balanc-
ing user comfort
autonomously, on own initiative, interacts with dierent users based on identified problem-
atic key meetings in order to avoid bother cost to users while persuading them to change
meeting flexibility
bases its non-myopic optimization on learned patterns of meetings
As shown in Figure 4.1, meeting requests are the information I get from the interface of TESLA
via the web interface (or via a proxy agent [Scerri et al., 2002] on an individual user’s hand-held
device, in case the users have proxy agents, who have the corresponding users’ preferences and
behavior models with a certain level of adjustable autonomy). TESLA focuses on minimizing
unnecessary interactions by detecting a small number of key meetings while negotiating with
people to adjust their flexibility. TESLA may interact with users’ proxy agents instead of the users
themselves.
4.2 TESLA Algorithms
The objective of this work is to come up with energy ecient schedules in commercial buildings
with a large number of meetings while considering (i) flexibility in meeting requests over time,
49
location and deadline; and (ii) user preferences with respect to energy and satisfaction. To account
for these two constraints, I provide two types of algorithms, which are at the heart of TESLA. First,
I provide algorithms that compute a schedule for known and predicted meeting requests which
have flexibility in time, location and deadline. Second, based on the schedule obtained, I provide
algorithms that detect meeting requests which if modified (to increase flexibility) can result in
significant energy savings.
4.2.1 Scheduling algorithms
Before describing my scheduling algorithms, I formally describe the scheduling problem. Let T
represent the entire set of time slots available and L represent the set of available locations each
day. A schedule request r
i
is represented as the tuple: r
i
=< a
i
; T
i
; L
i
;
i
; d
i
; n
i
>, where: a
i
is the
arrival time of the request, T
i
T is the set of preferred time slots for the start of the event and
L
i
L is a set of preferred locations. d
i
is the deadline by which the time and location for the
meeting should be notified to the user,
i
is the duration for the event and finally, n
i
is the number
of attendees.
The flexibility of the meeting request r
i
is a tuple denoted by
i
: <
T
i
,
L
i
,
d
i
>.
1
T
i
: time flexibility of meeting i.
T
i
=
jT
i
j1
jTj
i
100 (jTj>
i
; i.e.,jTj is 24 hours per day).
L
i
: location flexibility of meeting i.
L
i
=
jL
i
j1
jLj1
100 (jLj> 1).
d
i
: deadline flexibility of meeting i.
d
i
=
d
i
a
i
d
i
a
i
100, where d
i
is the latest notification
time (e.g., midnight on the meeting day) (d
i
> a
i
). 0
d
i
100
1
Flexibility is already present in the meeting request as its constraints, and is a measure of such constraints.
50
Figure 4.2: Disjoint sets of R
For instance, given only one time slot (jT
i
j = 1),
T
i
= 0 and all available time slots (jT
i
j =
jTj
i
+ 1),
T
i
= 100. Assuming that people give T
i
= 4–7pm on Monday and their meeting time
duration is 2 hours, then
T
i
= (4-1)/(24-2) 100 = 13.64%. Likewise, given only one location
slot (jL
i
j = 1),
L
i
= 0 and given all available locations (jL
i
j =jLj),
T
i
= 100.
I now define specific disjoint sets of meeting requests, R, that characterize dierent types of
scheduling algorithms, where t is the time to schedule a given set of requests R.
R
S
(t) =fi : d
i
= t and a
i
tg: a set of requests that have to be scheduled at time t
R
A
(t) =fi : d
i
< t and a
i
< tg: a set of requests that were assigned before time t
R
K
(t) =fi : d
i
> t and a
i
tg: a set of known future requests, which arrived before time t,
but will be scheduled in the future
R
U
(t) =fi : d
i
> t and a
i
> tg: a set of unknown future requests
As a simple example (shown in Figure 4.2), let us consider that we have 4 meeting requests
(r
1
; r
2
; r
3
, and r
4
), which are supposed to be scheduled on the same day. The current time is t.
According to the definition, R
S
(t) =fr
2
g; R
A
(t) =fr
1
g; R
K
(t) =fr
3
g, and R
U
(t) =fr
4
g.
Given a set of requests, R, I provide a two-stage stochastic mixed integer linear program
(SMILP) to compute a schedule that minimizes the overall energy consumption. Stochastic
51
programming has provided a framework for modeling optimization problems that involve un-
certainty [Beale, 1955; Dantzig, 1955; Kall and Wallace, 1994; Shapiro et al., 2009]. Whereas
deterministic optimization problems are formulated with known parameters, real world problems
almost invariably include some unknown parameters. In particular, my scheduling problem aims to
optimally schedule incrementally/dynamically arriving requests, and thus I should consider uncer-
tainty in terms of future requests, which makes deterministic optimization techniques inapplicable.
To address this challenge, I specifically formulate my scheduling problem as a two-stage stochastic
program. Here the decision variables are partitioned into two sets. The first stage variables are
decided before the actual realization of the uncertain parameters are known. Afterward, once the
random events have exhibited themselves, further decisions can be made by selecting the values
of the second stage. The second stage decision variables can be made to minimize penalties that
may occur as a result of the first stage decision. This SMILP will be run every time a new meeting
request arrives (or after a batch of meeting requests arrive in close succession).
The notation that will be employed in the SMILP is as follows:
x
i
l;t
is the first stage binary variable that is set to 1 if meeting request r
i
is scheduled in
location l starting at time t.
E
i
l;t
is a constant that is computed for a meeting request r
i
if it is scheduled in location l at
time t using the HV AC energy consumption equations.
C is a constant that indicates the reduction in energy consumption because of scheduling a
meeting in the previous time slot. Although I assumed that C is a constant for simplicity in
this work, it depends on dierent factors of previous meetings in practice.
52
e
i
l;t
is a continuous variable that corresponds to the energy consumed because of scheduling
meeting i in location l at time t. The value of this variable is aected based on whether
there is a meeting scheduled in the previous time slot (t 1), i.e., the reduction that would
occur at location l at time t if a meeting was scheduled at location l at time t 1.
2
e
i
l;t
= x
i
l;t
E
i
l;t
P
i
0
2Rnfig
x
i
0
l;t1
C.
S
i
l;t
is a value that indicates the satisfaction level obtained with users in meeting request r
i
for scheduling the meeting in location l at time t. B is a threshold on the satisfaction level
required by users.
M is an arbitrarily large positive constant.
Q(x;) is the value function of future energy consumption, where represents uncertainty
over the second stage problem (i.e., future meeting situations in the problem). determines
a vector of parameters, (w; q).
w
j
l;t
is the second stage binary variable that is set to 1 if meeting request r
j
in a future meeting
request set is scheduled in location l starting at time t.
q
j
l;t
is a continuous second stage variable that corresponds to the future energy consumed
because of scheduling meeting j in location l at time t.
I first provide the SMILP and a detailed explanation of the constraints.
2
e
i
l;t
gets aected by a meeting in the previous time slot in the same location. This is because adjacent meetings
aect the indoor temperature, which makes HV ACs operate dierently to maintain the desired temperature level.
53
min e +E[Q(x;)] (4.1)
fChoose the optimal first stage variables that minimizes the sum of first stage costs
and the expected value of the second stageg
s:t:
e
X
i2RnR
U
X
t2T
X
l2L
e
i
l;t
; (4.2)
fComputing the first stage cost eg
e
i
l;t
= x
i
l;t
E
i
l;t
X
i
0
2RnR
U
nfig
x
i
0
l;t1
C; 8i2 Rn R
U
; l2 L; t2 T (4.3)
fComputing energy consumption while considering the back-to-back meeting eectg
e
i
l;t
0; 8i2 Rn R
U
; l2 L; t2 T (4.4)
X
t2T
X
l2L
x
i
l;t
S
i
l;t
B; 8i2 Rn R
U
(4.5)
fChecking if the computed schedule maintains the given comfort level Bg
X
i2RnR
U
x
i
l;t
1; 8l2 L; t2 T (4.6)
X
i
0
2RnR
U
nfig
t+
i
1
X
t
0
=t
x
i
0
l;t
0
M(1 x
i
l;t
); 8l2 L; i2 Rn R
U
; t2 T (4.7)
fChecking the allocation restrictions that for each assignment slot, only one meeting
can be scheduled considering the given time duration of meetingg
x
i
l;t
2f0; 1g; 8i2 Rn R
U
; l2 L; t2 T (4.8)
fThe first stage binary variableg
Q(x;)
X
j2R
U
X
l2L
X
t2T
q
j
l;t
; (4.9)
fComputing the second stage cost Qg
54
q
j
l;t
= w
j
l;t
E
j
l;t
X
i2RnR
U
x
i
l;t1
C
X
i2RnR
U
x
i
l;t+1
C
X
j
0
2R
U
nf jg
w
j
0
l;t1
C; (4.10)
fComputing energy consumption while considering the back-to-back meeting eect
caused by the first and second stage variablesg
q
j
l;t
0; 8 j2 R
U
; l2 L; t2 T (4.11)
X
j2R
U
w
j
l;t
1; 8l2 L; t2 T (4.12)
X
j2R
U
t+
i
1
X
t
0
=t
w
j
l;t
0
M(1 x
i
l;t
); 8l2 L; i2 Rn R
U
; t2 T (4.13)
fChecking the allocation restrictions against the first stage assignment slotsg
X
j
0
2R
U
nf jg
t+
j
1
X
t
0
=t
w
j
0
l;t
0
M(1 w
j
l;t
); 8l2 L; j2 R
U
; t2 T (4.14)
fChecking the allocation restrictions against the second stage assignment slotsg
w
j
l;t
2f0; 1g; 8 j2 R
U
; l2 L; t2 T (4.15)
fThe second stage binary variableg
The objective of the SMILP above is to choose the optimal first stage variables (i.e., the optimal
assignment of meeting requests to locations and time slots that is characterized by the solution,
x
i
l;t
). The optimal first stage variable, x
, is selected in a way that the sum of first stage costs e (i.e.,
the energy consumption when the current meeting request is scheduled) and the expected value of
the second stage or recourse costsE[Q(x;)] (i.e., the expected energy consumption that will be
realized by future meeting requests) is minimized. In this formulation, at the first stage I have to
55
make a decision before the realization of the uncertain data, which is viewed as a random vector
that determines future meeting requests, is known. At the second stage, after a realization of
becomes available, I optimize a behavior by solving an appropriate optimization problem.
Constraints (4.2) – (4.8) are a set of enforcement for deciding first stage variables, and con-
straints (4.9) – (4.15) enforce conditions for second stage variables. More specifically, constraint
(4.3) is for computing energy consumption considering the back-to-back meeting eect. In par-
ticular, I subtract from the energy consumed by this meeting indexed by i at time t, the impact
due to meetings (indexed by i
0
), that were scheduled at the prior time slot t 1. Constraint (4.5)
is for checking if the computed schedule maintains the given comfort level B. Constraints (4.6)
and (4.7) are the allocation restrictions that for each assignment slot, only one meeting can be
scheduled considering the given time duration of meeting. In particular, M in constraint (4.7) is an
arbitrarily large positive constant to enforce only one meeting is scheduled at a location during the
duration of the meeting. If meeting i is assigned to location l and time t (x
i
l;t
= 1), then any other
meeting requests cannot be assigned to the same slot. If x
i
l;t
= 0, the constraint does not block any
other meeting requests from being assigned to that slot as the right-hand side of the equation is
not bounded due to an arbitrarily large constant of M. Constraint (4.9) is to compute the optimal
value of the second stage problem while satisfying constraints (4.10) – (4.15) which are similar to
constraints (4.3) – (4.8). Specifically, constraint (4.10) is for computing the energy reduction that
would occur if there are any consecutive meetings among the requests in R
U
(i.e., check with w)
and if any future meetings have this back-to-back eect with either already assigned meetings or
ones that have to be scheduled in Rn R
U
(i.e., check with x).
I now describe the sample average approximation (SAA) method [Ahmed et al., 2002; Pagnon-
celli et al., 2009] to solve the given SMILP. The main idea of the SAA approach to solve stochastic
56
programs is as follows. A sample
1
;:::;
N
realizations of the random vector is generated, and
consequently the expected value functionE[Q(x;)] in the stochastic program (1) is approximated
by the weighted average function
P
N
n=1
p
U
n
Q(x;
n
), where p
U
n
is the likelihood that
n
is realized.
Recall that is the random vector that determines future meeting requests in my formulation (i.e.,
each realization
n
has a dierent number of future meeting requests and corresponding request
tuples). More specifically, a probability distribution p
T
over the possible range of total meeting
requests per day is given (shown in Figures 2.8(b) & 2.9(b)). Then, the likelihood that k more
meetings will arrive on the same day assuming we currently have s meetings so far is equivalent to
the likelihood that
n
is realized with k unknown future requests: p
U
n
(k) = p
T
(s + k). For those k
future meeting requests in R
U
n
, I generate random request tuples (specifically, T
i
& L
i
) based on
the actual distribution over the assignment spots as shown in Figures 2.8(a) & 2.9(a). Then, for a
sample n (1 n N), the original SMILP is reformulated as follows:
57
min e +
N
X
n=1
p
U
n
Q(x;
n
) (4.16)
fUsing SAA, the expected value of the second stage cost is approximated by
the weighted average function. Then, I still choose the optimal first stage
variable that minimizes the sum of the first and second stage costsg
s:t:
Constraints (4.2) – (4.8),
Q(x;
n
)
X
j2R
U
n
X
l2L
X
t2T
q
n
j;l;t
; (4.17)
q
n
j;l;t
= w
n
j;l;t
E
j;l;t
X
i2RnR
U
x
i;l;t1
C
X
i2RnR
U
x
i;l;t+1
C
X
j
0
2R
U
n
nf jg
w
n
j
0
;l;t1
C; (4.18)
q
n
j;l;t
0; 8 j2 R
U
n
; l2 L; t2 T (4.19)
X
j2R
U
n
w
n
j;l;t
1; 8l2 L; t2 T (4.20)
X
j2R
U
n
t+
i
1
X
t
0
=t
w
n
j;l;t
0
M(1 x
i;l;t
); 8l2 L; i2 Rn R
U
; t2 T (4.21)
X
j
0
2R
U
n
nf jg
t+
j
1
X
t
0
=t
w
n
j
0
;l;t
0
M(1 w
n
j;l;t
); 8l2 L; j2 R
U
n
; t2 T (4.22)
w
n
j;l;t
2f0; 1g; 8 j2 R
U
n
; l2 L; t2 T (4.23)
N
X
n=1
p
U
n
= 1 (4.24)
fp
U
n
is the likelihood that
n
is realized, where is a random variable that
determines future meeting requests Ug
58
The obtained sample average approximation (4.16) of the stochastic program is then solved
using a standard branch and bound algorithm such as those implemented in commercial integer
programming solvers such as CPLEX.
As benchmark algorithms for comparison purposes, I provide two optimization heuristics:
myopic and full-knowledge. I have the myopic optimization algorithm, which obtains a schedule
by considering the following request set: R = (R
A
(t)[ R
S
(t)[ R
K
(t)). A schedule and energy
consumption are obtained without accounting for future unknown meetings. Thus, the myopic
heuristic only considers the first stage decision variables in my SMILP. In the full-knowledge
method, I compute the final schedule while assuming that the entire set of meeting requests R is
given, which is ideal. Thus, for the full-knowledge method, I have one actual realization with
probability 1.0 for computing the second stage costs in the SMILP. The performance comparison
results will be provided in Section 4.3.
4.2.2 Identifying key meetings
TESLA computes the optimal schedule considering the given flexibility (or scheduling constraints)
of meetings. It can obtain more energy-ecient schedules by increasing flexibility (i.e., relaxing
those constraints). I now provide an algorithm that finds meeting requests, which if made more
flexible will reduce energy consumption significantly.
Algorithm 2 IdentifyKeyMeetings (R)
1: U ;
2: fInitialize a set of key meetingsg
3:
4: for all I 2
R
do
5: fR is a set of requests.g
6: if IsSavingCandidate (I) then
7: U U[ I
8:
9: return U
59
Algorithm 3 IsSavingCandidate (I)
1: V
I
CalExpEnergySavings(
I
,f
0
I;1
;:::;
0
I;k
g)
2: f
I
is an initially given flexibility of meetings in I, and
0
I;k
is one of the desired flexibility options for
meetings in I. CalExpEnergySavings computes energy gains, V
I
, by relaxing flexibility of meeting
requests in I.g
3:
4: ifjIj = 1 then
5: if V
I
> then
6: fIf the computed energy gains V
I
is higher than a given threshold value, it is considered as a key
meeting.g
7: return TRUE
8: else
9: return FALSE
10: else ifjIj> 1 then
11: fRecursively call IsSavingCandidate with possible subsetsg
12: for all i2 I do
13: I’ Infig
14: V
I
0 CalExpEnergySavings(
I
0,f
0
I
0
;1
;:::;
0
I
0
;k
g)
15: if V
I
V
I
0 > 0 then
16: fOnly if the energy savings are monotonically increasing by adding a meeting request i (or
monotonically decreasing by excluding a meeting request i), proceedg
17: return IsSavingCandidate (I
0
)
Algorithm 2 describes the overall flow of the algorithm. I first initialize a set that will contain
key meetings identified by the algorithm (line 1). For each subset of the power set of meeting
requests R, I then examine whether or not the current meeting set I is a key meeting set by relying
on Algorithm 3 (line 6).
Algorithm 3 recursively determines if the given meeting set I is a candidate set that gives
significant potential energy savings. The meeting set I is detected as a key meeting set only if the
expected energy savings of meeting requests in I are monotonically increasing and show higher
energy improvements than the given threshold value (; a certain level of additional energy savings
that we desire to achieve with the selected key meetings) by relaxing their flexibility. To handle
this, I first compute the expected energy savings of the meeting set I when its flexibility level is
changed from the initial level
I
to the desired level
0
I
assuming the other meetings’ flexibility
levels are fixed (line 1). The expected energy saving value of meeting set I, V
I
= (E
I
E
0
I
)=E
I
60
(0 V
I
1), where E
I
is the current total energy consumption with the given level of flexibility
I
, and E
0
I
is the reduced total energy consumption if the meeting set I’s flexibility is changed
to one of k possible options,
0
I;k
, while others keep their given flexibility levels. In this work, I
consider a heuristic for setting the threshold value to investigate whether or not the current meeting
set I is an energy saving candidate set: a fixed single threshold value (line 5; e.g., 0.4 as a
universal threshold).
4.3 Empirical Validation
I evaluate the performance of TESLA and experimentally show that it can conserve energy by
providing more energy-ecient schedules in commercial buildings. At the end of this section,
I provide actual survey results that I have conducted on schedule flexibilities of real users. The
experiments were run on Intel Core2 Duo 2.53GHz CPU with 8GB main memory. I solved the
MILP formulations using CPLEX version 12.1. All techniques were evaluated for 100 independent
trials and I report the average values. Energy consumption was computed using the simulator
described earlier in Section 2.4.
4.3.1 Simulation Results
In this section, I provide the simulation results (i) to verify if flexibility really helps TESLA
compute energy-ecient schedules; (ii) to extensively evaluate the overall performance of the
SAA method while varying the sample size and flexibility; and (iii) to measure energy saving
benefits by identifying key meetings and by considering the cancellation rate.
61
Figure 4.3: Energy savings: Actual - the amount of energy consumed in simulation based on the
past schedules obtained from the current manual reservation system; Random - energy consumption
while randomly perturbing the starting time and location of meeting requests from the same past
schedules while keeping meeting time duration; Optimal - Energy consumption measured in
simulation based on optimal schedules computed from an SMILP with the fully known meeting
request set and full flexibility
4.3.1.1 Does flexibility help?
As an important first step in deploying TESLA , I first verified if the agent could save more energy
with more flexibility while scheduling given meeting and event requests. To that end, I compared
the energy consumption of three dierent approaches using the real-world meeting data mentioned
in Section 2.5: (i) the current benchmark approach in use at the testbed building; (ii) a random
method that randomly assigns time and location for meetings; and (iii) the optimal method using
the full-knowledge optimization technique described in Section 4.2.
Figure 4.3 shows the average daily energy consumption in kWh computed based on schedules
from the three algorithms above. In the figure, the consumption is the amount of energy consumed
based on the past schedules obtained from the current manual reservation system, which shows a
very similar performance to the random approach. The optimal method assuming the full amount
62
(a) Scalability: runtime (b) Accuracy: average error
Figure 4.4: Scalability and accuracy while varying the number of samples (N)
of flexibility (i.e., 24 hours for
T
, 35 rooms for
L
and delay the deadline before which the final
schedule should be informed for
d
) achieved statistically significant energy savings of 50.05%
compared to the current energy consumption at the testbed site. These savings are practically
significant, and also statistically significant (paired-sample t-test; p< 0.01). These savings are
equivalent to annual savings of about $18,600 considering an energy rate of $0.193/kWh [U.S.
Department of Labor, 2012] and CO
2
emissions from the energy use of 5.5 homes for one year.
Thus, flexibility can help save energy.
4.3.1.2 Online scheduling method with flexibility: Determining the sample size in the
TESLA SMILP
In this section, I first investigated the runtime and solution qualities for solving the SMILP while
varying the number of samples (see Figure 4.4). Figure 4.4(a) shows the results of the runtime
analysis in seconds (y-axis) for sample sizes N = 10 to 100 (x-axis). As shown in the figure, the
runtime increases in an exponential fashion as the sample size N increases. However, Figure 4.4(b)
63
Figure 4.5: Energy savings while varying flexibility (USC)
shows that its solution quality also increases (y-axis) (i.e., the estimated optimality gap decreases)
as the number of samples N increases. For evaluating the generated solution for each of sample
size N, I generated M independent samples (i.e., replications) of the uncertain parameters, and
evaluated the obtained solution in each m2 M replication. In this work, I specifically used 1,000
independent replications for measuring the estimated optimality. The percentage error is obtained
by comparing the full-knowledge schedules based on actual realization of each of the 1000 samples
with the schedule from the SMILP. Based on this result, throughout the paper, I set N = 50 to solve
the SAA problem. This sample size has a reasonable runtime without a significant compromise in
solution quality.
4.3.1.3 Performance of online scheduling method with flexibility
I next compared solution qualities of the three scheduling algorithms in TESLA presented in
Section 4.2.1. Figure 4.5 shows that how much each algorithm saves when compared to the optimal
value (i.e., full-knowledge optimization assuming the full flexibility) while varying the time and
64
Table 4.1: Performance comparison between SAA and myopic
@
@
@
Max Min Average
Optimality dierence 57.89% 0.50% 12.73%
location flexibility level (assuming 0% deadline flexibility). The flexibility in my model represents
a 3-dimensional space (time, location and deadline), which I have thoroughly explored. I show
results exploring deadline flexibility later.
The optimality percentage on the y-axis of Figure 4.5 is computed as follows: (E
a
E
c
)=(E
a
E
o
). Here E
a
is the actual energy consumption without any flexibility, E
o
is the optimal energy con-
sumption, and E
c
is the computed energy consumption using three dierent scheduling algorithms
that I compare using the real meeting data.
Figure 4.5 shows the average optimality in percentage of each algorithm (M: myopic, P:
predictive non-myopic (SAA) and F: full-knowledge) while varying the location flexibility (
L
;
x-axis) and time flexibility (
T
; each graph assumed the dierent amount of
T
as indicated in the
legend). In the figure, for each pair of flexibility values (
T
;
L
), I report the average optimality in
percentage (i.e., 100% indicates the optimal value, and 0% means that there was no improvement
from the actual energy consumption). For instance, when flexibility (
T
;
L
) = (31.5%, 58.8%),
the myopic method achieved an optimality of 50.8%. In the figure, higher values indicate better
performance.
As shown in Figure 4.5, as users provide more flexibility, TESLA can compute schedules
with less energy consumption. The gain in optimality from myopic to predictive non-myopic
(SAA) is because the latter can leverage user flexibility to put a meeting in a suboptimal spot at
the meeting request time to account for future meetings, yielding better results at the actual day
65
of meetings. For example, a flexible meeting request can be moved away from a known popular
time-location spot. I conclude that (i) the predictive non-myopic (SAA) method is superior to
the myopic method. Table 4.1 shows the average performance comparison results between the
predictive non-myopic (SAA) method and the myopic technique. As shown in the table, the
maximum and average optimality dierences between the two methods (i.e., optimality of the
SAA - optimality of the myopic) are 57.89% and 12.73%, respectively, which are significant. In
addition, for 12.50% of cases, the predictive non-myopic (SAA) optimization showed over 20%
higher optimality than the myopic method; (ii) the predictive non-myopic (SAA) method performs
almost as well as the full-knowledge optimization (about 98%)
3
; and (iii) full flexibility is not
required to start accruing benefits of flexibility.
In the real-world, it is hard to imagine that all people will simply comply and change their
flexibility to achieve such optimality. Thus, I provide one additional result shown in Table 4.2
which varies the percentage of meetings that will have flexibility (p
f
). I show
T
along the rows
and
L
along the columns. In particular, the value of row 10 and column 5 (highlighted in the table)
shows the optimality achieved by the predictive method assuming that 20% of meetings (randomly
selected) have (
T
;
L
) = (0%, 23.5%) flexibility and the remaining 80% have no flexibility. My
main conclusions are: (i) if p
f
increases, a higher optimality can be achieved; and (ii) flexibility in
a small number of meetings can lead to significant energy reduction. This motivates considering
more intelligent identification of key meetings to change their flexibility (described in the next
section).
3
The average performance of the predictive non-myopic (SAA) optimization depends on the prediction method
of future requests. I, thus, additionally tested a more sophisticated prediction method considering the time factor that
is one of key features determining the overall trend of requests (i.e., when the meeting requests arrive at the system
to be scheduled; e.g., regular semester vs. summer/ winter break). With this additional consideration, the predictive
non-myopic (SAA) method improved the overall performance of the predictive method by 1.1%.
66
Table 4.2: % of optimal energy savings: varying
T
,
L
, and p
f
(USC)
T. flex. (
T
)
Location flexibility (
L
)
Alg. p
f
23.5 47.1 70.6 94.1
0
M
1.0 6.6 6.7 17.8 23.3
0.8 5.6 6.0 14.5 21.2
0.5 4.9 4.9 13.8 18.2
0.2 3.3 3.8 8.4 12.0
P
1.0 9.7 9.8 22.7 24.8
0.8 8.6 9.3 20.9 23.2
0.5 6.4 6.9 15.6 18.6
0.2 4.2 4.9 9.8 12.9
F
1.0 9.9 10.1 23.6 25.8
0.8 8.3 8.6 20.7 24.0
0.5 6.7 6.9 16.9 19.1
0.2 4.9 5.1 11.3 13.6
31.5
M 1.0 46.3 46.5 55.8 61.4
P 1.0 48.1 48.5 62.1 62.7
F
1.0 49.0 49.2 63.0 63.1
0.8 41.9 43.3 55.5 57.6
0.5 29.9 30.7 43.9 44.5
0.2 16.1 16.7 26.9 27.2
67.5
M 1.0 81.8 82.5 89.6 96.0
P 1.0 84.4 86.3 95.4 96.8
F
1.0 86.3 86.8 96.0 97.5
0.8 73.3 73.5 87.9 91.3
0.5 53.7 54.4 65.0 67.8
0.2 29.4 30.6 38.2 41.4
(M: myopic, P: predictive non-myopic (SAA), F: full-knowledge)
Table 4.3: Percentage of optimal energy savings: varying
d
(USC)
H
H
H
H
H
H
Alg.
d
0.0 22.2 44.4 66.7 88.9
M 82.5 83.4 84.0 84.2 84.2
P 86.3 86.4 86.7 86.7 86.8
F 86.8 86.8 86.8 86.8 86.8
(M: myopic, P: predictive non-myopic (SAA), F: full-knowledge)
I also compared the performance of the three algorithms while varying the deadline flexibility,
d
. In Table 4.3, columns indicate dierent amounts of deadline flexibility and values are the
67
Figure 4.6: Energy savings while varying flexibility (SMU)
optimality of each algorithm assuming a fixed time and location flexibility (
T
;
L
) = (67.5%,
47.1%). As I increase the deadline flexibility, both myopic and predictive non-myopic (SAA)
methods converge to the full-knowledge optimization result. This is because as the deadline
flexibility increases, scheduling can be delayed until more information is available. In this
particular case of
T
and
L
, I do not necessarily see significant benefits by providing more deadline
flexibility since the myopic and predictive non-myopic (SAA) methods already achieved fairly
high optimality compared to the full-knowledge method. While the optimality percentage changes
are small, given the vast amount of energy consumed by large-scale facilities, these reductions can
lead to significant energy savings. I am investigating conditions where my algorithms get more
benefits by deadline flexibility.
The same types of analysis are performed with another data set from SMU and results are
presented in Figure 4.6. The figure shows the average optimality in percentage of each algorithm
(M: myopic, P: predictive non-myopic (SAA) and F: full-knowledge) on the y-axis while varying
the time flexibility (
T
; each graph assumed the dierent amount of
T
as indicated in the legend)
68
Table 4.4: Percentage of optimal energy savings: varying
d
(SMU)
H
H
H
H
H
H
Alg.
d
0.0 22.2 44.4 66.7 88.9
M 85.30 87.22 89.02 89.41 90.06
P 93.01 93.05 94.56 94.87 95.14
F 95.21 95.21 95.21 95.21 95.21
(M: myopic, P: predictive non-myopic (SAA), F: full-knowledge)
Table 4.5: Energy improvement of identified key meetings (%)
H
H
H
H
H
H
0
(0,23.5) (0,47.1) (0,70.6) (31.5,23.5) (31.5,47.1)
(0,23.5) - - - - -
(0,47.1) 16.08 - - - -
(0,70.6) 30.08 29.17 - - -
(31.5,23.5) 32.05 - - - -
(31.5,47.1) 46.18 36.27 - 29.17 -
(31.5,70.6) 46.52 38.33 34.36 31.07 26.08
and location flexibility (
L
; x-axis). I assume the deadline flexibility (
d
) of 0%. Similar to earlier
results, the predictive method achieved about 97% optimality compared to the full-knowledge
optimization and showed higher value than the myopic approach. I also compared the performance
of the three algorithms while varying the deadline flexibility. In Table 4.4, values are the optimality
of each algorithm assuming a fixed time and location flexibility, (31.5%, 47.1%). Here I see more
pronounced energy savings at SMU as
d
increases compared to the USC results.
4.3.1.4 Performance of identifying key meetings
I evaluated the performance of the algorithm to identify key meetings for energy reduction. In
the tests, I selected 10 meetings individually using the algorithm presented in Section 4.2.2 and
calculated the average energy savings if those selected meetings changed their flexibility.
69
Table 4.5 shows the average energy savings as described for various flexibility transitions.
Columns indicate the initial level of flexibility ( = (
T
;
L
)) and rows show the requested level
of flexibility (
0
= (
0T
;
0L
)). For instance, the value in row 4 and column 3 (highlighted in the
table) indicates a 29.17% average energy savings improvement if flexibility of 10 key meetings
are changed from (0%, 47.1%) to (0%, 70.6%). An important interpretation of that results is
that changing the flexibility of key meetings, when those ones are from an appropriately chosen
set, contributed to significant energy savings. I also tested how much energy can be saved if key
meetings are chosen simultaneously rather than independently. Assuming the current flexibility
is (0%, 23.5%) (column 2 in Table 4.5), if I choose 10 key meetings at the same time using the
same algorithm presented in Section 4.2.2, the average energy savings were improved by 10.3%
(i.e., 44.48% of energy saving improvements on average). In the future, I will investigate another
heuristic to set a feasible threshold value based on a learned profile of user likelihood of changing
meeting flexibility.
4.3.1.5 Considering the cancellation rate
According to the real meeting data collected for eight months (January through August in 2012)
at USC, about 10.12% (3,245 out of 32,065) of the total meeting requests were canceled, which
gives me another insight to achieve further energy savings by utilizing this feature. To incorporate
this feature into my SMILP formulation
4
, I change constraint (7) as follows:
Pr(
P
i
0
2RnR
U
nfig
P
t+
i
1
t
0
=t
x
i
0
;l;t
0 M(1 x
i;l;t
)) 1
c
The constraint above is given in the form of the chance constrained programming that relaxes
the allocation restrictions (i.e., with a probability of
c
, the given allocation restrictions can be
4
Note that canceled meetings were not considered while scheduling meetings in the earlier results.
70
Figure 4.7: Average energy improvement while considering the cancellation rate of meeting
requests
violated). In this work, I tested how much additional energy savings can be achieved by allowing
the system to overbook meeting rooms that are taken by meeting requests that may be canceled,
which is systematically controlled by the cancellation rate (
c
) in the stochastic program. If any
schedule conflicts occur by TESLA, TESLA greedily finds the currently available best slots in
terms of energy savings for resolving conflict in meetings.
A result is provided in Figure 4.7. The y-axis in the figure indicates the average energy saving
improvements in percentage while varying the cancellation rate (
c
) on the x-axis. These average
values were measured over 100 independent trials. As shown in the figure, as I set a higher
c
,
the overall average energy savings increase. In particular, with 10.12% cancellation rate that was
obtained from the real-world data, the expected energy saving improvement was about 14.78%,
which is fairly significant.
71
Figure 4.8: Energy savings by TESLA: the percentage of energy savings per each energy consumer
and factor
4.4 Analysis: Savings due to TESLA
There are three major components that aect energy consumption in commercial buildings: HV ACs
(accounting for 35% of the entire energy consumption in commercial buildings), lighting (27%),
and electronic devices (about 10%) [U.S. Department of Energy, 2010]. TESLA focuses on
these three energy consumers to save energy by computing energy-ecient schedules that exploit
key factors that aect energy consumption of each building component. Figure 4.8 shows the
percentage of energy savings per each energy consumer and factor in TESLA assuming an actually
measured time and location flexibility (
T
,
L
) = (25.34%, 16.05%) from surveys of real users.
For instance, as shown in the figure, 47.4% of energy savings by TESLA is achieved through
more energy-ecient operations of HV ACs. More specifically, TESLA shifts meetings to suitable
smaller oces or non-peak time and packs meetings together, and those strategies result in a
significant energy reduction for HV ACs.
4.4.1 HV ACs
Key assumptions The following assumptions are made in TESLA :
72
(a) Average room usage density (b) Room size
Figure 4.9: Energy saving analysis: room size
Figure 4.10: Energy savings only by HV ACs (Non-peak Time)
HV ACs are centrally regulated by the university facility management team to satisfy two
pre-defined temperature ranges: occupied time zone (8am to 6pm: 70–75F) and unoccupied
time zone (rest of the hours: 60–80F).
While optimizing schedules, the threshold of people’s comfort level was set to 50%, which
is a configurable parameter.
73
Factors impacting HV AC energy As shown in Figure 4.8, given the above assumptions, HV ACs
accounted for 47.4% of the overall energy savings. Numbers in the parentheses below indicate the
amount of energy savings by each of the following three factors:
Room Size: TESLA focuses on assigning meetings to smaller spaces while considering
the number of meeting attendees, since a larger room requires more energy than a smaller
room when occupied for the same amount of time (38.3%). Figure 4.9 shows the actual
and optimal usage density and the physical size (y-axis) of 35 dierent rooms (x-axis) in
the testbed building at USC. As shown in the figure, TESLA generates the schedule that
uses 18.16% less space compared to the actual schedule, which clearly proves that TESLA
provides more energy-ecient schedules by assigning meetings to smaller spaces.
Non-peak Time: TESLA avoids the peak time in terms of energy and popularity considering
the given constraints/flexibility. Since an unoccupied time zone requires less energy than
occupied time zone when the same room is occupied for the same amount of time, TESLA
focuses on assigning meetings under an unoccupied time zone as much as possible (29.5%).
However, since an unoccupied time zone has a wider regulated temperature range, this
optimization may cause a drop in the average comfort level of people. While this flexibility
of holding the meeting at non-peak time is assumed to be part of the meeting request, this
drop in comfort level is worth further investigation. The first point to note is that the amount
of energy savings achieved by the non-peak time factor itself is less significant (i.e., 13.93%)
compared to other factors. Thus, in Figure 4.10, I provide a result that shows how the non-
peak time factor aects the overall energy savings (y-axis) while varying the unoccupied
time zone temperature (x-axis). As shown in the figure, as I reduce a temperature range
74
for the unoccupied time zone, the amount of energy savings by the non-peak time factor
decreases, but TESLA can still achieve meaningful energy savings while satisfying the given
comfort level constraint. Furthermore, TESLA provides a flexible architecture that allows
people to configure the temperature value accordingly under dierent situations.
Packing Meetings: TESLA focused on packing meetings together in terms of the time
interval between meetings in the same room. When a meeting ends, the room is conditioned
to a pre-defined environment. This built-up thermal momentum can benefit later meetings
scheduled in the same room in close proximity by reducing the number of changes of HV AC
operations, which saves much more energy (32.2%).
4.4.2 Lighting
Key assumptions The following assumptions are made in TESLA :
The standard nominal values were used for the lighting configuration in spaces.
When the room was occupied, the full (100%) lighting level was considered.
When the room was unoccupied, 0% lighting level was considered.
Factors impacting lighting energy As shown in Figure 4.8, given the above assumptions, the
lighting sources accounted for 37.5% of the overall energy savings. The entire energy savings
are caused by dierent room size; specifically, TESLA focuses on assigning meetings to smaller
spaces while considering the number of meeting attendees, since a larger room requires more
energy than a smaller room when occupied for the same amount of time (see Figure 4.9).
75
4.4.3 Electronics
Key assumptions The following assumptions are made in TESLA :
Assumed average number of devices in each room was considered to calculate the correct
energy consumption.
5
When the room was occupied, 80% of the devices were used.
When the room was unoccupied, 0% of the devices were used.
Factors impacting electronics energy As shown in Figure 4.8, given the above assumptions,
the electronics accounted for 15.1% of the overall energy savings. The entire energy savings
are caused by dierent room size; specifically, TESLA focuses on assigning meetings to smaller
spaces while considering the number of meeting attendees, since a larger room has more devices
in the testbed building, and thus it requires more energy than a smaller room when occupied for
the same amount of time (see Figure 4.9).
4.5 Human Subject Experiments
The goal of human subject experiments is to support the results provided in the previous section
by answering several questions: (i) are people flexible in real situations?; (ii) how flexible are
people in modifying their requests?; (iii) will people in the identified key meetings actually agree
to change their flexibility to contribute energy savings?; and (iv) what would be an eective way
for an agent to persuade people? To answer these, I measure the amount of reported flexibility
change while varying feedback about the energy usage.
5
While evaluating TESLA, I considered the assumed average number of electronic devices including the actual
number of devices existing in each room as well as the average number of devices that people bring with them.
76
Figure 4.11: Screenshot of online survey: people were asked to indicate their meeting requests
and flexibility.
I conducted two surveys on a pilot sample of participants (students on campus): (i) an online
survey to understand flexibility of those who are using the testbed building; and (ii) a survey to
measure flexibility change due to messaging.
4.5.1 Survey for initial flexibility
I conducted an online survey to understand the flexibility of meeting attendees (shown in Fig-
ure 4.11). The procedure to conduct this survey is as follows: I recruited 32 students who have
used the meeting reservation system at the tested building and their facilities. They filled out a
survey, indicating meeting requests and flexibility. I analyzed their profile including the details of
their meeting requests and their flexibility in terms of time and locations considering their real
constraints. Tables 4.6 & 4.7 show a list of detailed questions in the questionnaire used during the
survey.
77
Table 4.6: Basic Profile Questionnaire
Question Answer (Scale)
Q
1
. Gender? Male / Female
Q
2
. Position at USC? Undergraduate / Graduate / Sta / Faculty
Q
3
. Age?
20 or under / 21–25 / 26–30 / 31–35 /
36–40 / 41 or above
Q
4
. Average frequency to use
0 – 10 or more
USC Leavey collaborative workrooms per week?
Q
5
. Average meeting attendees? 1 – 10 or more
Q
6
. Average meeting time duration? (in hour) 1 – 5 or more
Q
7
. How much do you consider energy savings
1 (Not at all) – 7 (Extremely)
while requesting scheduling meetings?
Q
8
. I consider myself an environmentalist. 1 (Disagree) – 7 (Agree)
Table 4.7: Survey I: Questionnaire
Assumption (A)
Let us assume that you would like to schedule a meeting next week
using the central meeting reservation system, which is currently used
at USC Leavey library.
Question (Q)
Q
1
. What is your preferred time range to start the meeting on each
day of the week? (Note: Consider your actual class and other meeting
constraints while answering this.)
Q
2
. What locations do you prefer for your meeting among the rooms
that you chosen? For your information, the number in the parentheses
indicates the maximum capacity of each room. (Note: Please try to
answer this based on your past experience at USC Leavey library.)
Figure 5.8 shows the distribution of the time and location flexibility. The x-axis shows the
discretized flexibility level and their corresponding frequency in percentage is provided on the
y-axis. People reported varied levels of time and location flexibility. The average time flexibility
(
T
) was 25.34% and the measured minimum and maximum time flexibility were 9.86% and
42.86%, respectively. The average location flexibility (
L
) was 16.05% and its range was 0 to
38.24%. This survey result clearly shows that people have fairly diverse flexibility levels and
provides the insight that there is a significant potential to conserve energy by exploiting scheduling
flexibility in TESLA.
78
(a) Time flexibility (b) Location flexibility
Figure 4.12: Diversity of people’s flexibility
4.5.2 Survey for requested flexibility
I conducted a second survey to understand what types of feedback are most eective to change
flexibility while scheduling meetings. I consider two test conditions: (i) feedback without moti-
vation (Test Group I) (e.g., if necessary, do you think you will be able to provide more options
in terms of time and location?), and (ii) feedback with motivation including average flexibility
provided, and environmental motives (Test Group II) (e.g., on average, people who are using this
system give 3–4 hour range for their available time on each day and 5–6 rooms for their available
locations. This helps the system to compute more energy-ecient schedules that lead to energy
savings by about 30% at the testbed building, which is equivalent to $5,765 per year. Do you think
you will be able to provide more options in terms of time and location?). A more detailed list of
questions is shown in Table 4.8.
Hypothesis 2. More informed feedback (provided to subjects in Test Group II) will be more
eective to conserve energy than feedback without motivation (Test Group I).
79
To test the hypothesis above, I recruited 22 students with the same requirement of the earlier
survey. Subjects were randomly tested under two dierent conditions when they accessed the
online survey, and each test group had 11 individuals respectively.
Table 4.9 shows the average flexibility change in percentage (0–100%) of two test groups. Thus,
higher values indicate that more participants comply and increase their scheduling flexibility to
higher levels. When I provided more informed feedback including environmental motives (Group
II), participants tripled their flexibility increase percentage (17.12%). In Group I, participants
only increase their flexibility level by 5.15% on average. The dierence is statistically significant
and provides strong evidence for the hypothesis (t-test; p< 0.01). This study shows that we can
conserve energy by investigating methods to improve motivation to conserve energy by adjusting
their flexibility.
In this trial study, I have learned that although occupants in commercial buildings do not have a
direct financial incentive in saving energy, proper motivations can achieve a higher compliance rate
for the energy-related suggestion with a specific focus on their flexibility. This study specifically
provides the insights that there is a significant potential to conserve energy by investigating eective
and tailored methods to improve occupants’ motivation to conserve energy while handling energy-
ecient scheduling problems. However, at the same time, in order to deploy my TESLA system
in the real-world while keeping people in the loop, there are a number of research challenges that
have to be addressed. Most notably, in a commercial setup where people do not have a direct
financial incentive to save energy, a dierent incentive mechanism to eectively motivate them
and keep them as active participants in energy saving activities might potentially be required;
determining the importance of such mechanisms or if they are needed in the first place is a topic
for future work [Abrahmase et al., 2005; Anderson et al., 2012; Carrico and Riemer, 2011; Faruqui
80
et al., 2010; Wood and Neal, 2009]. Over time, people will be able to observe the impact of their
input (e.g., flexibility) while scheduling meetings and whether or not people engaged with TESLA
on a day-to-day basis will provide flexibility to the extent they could remains to be determined.
Thus, while this paper has provided a critical first step in flexibility-based energy savings, and
provided algorithms to accomplish such savings, a future implementation will need to take the
next step to investigate topics such as motivation and incentives.
81
Table 4.8: Survey II: Questionnaire
A.
Let us assume that you would like to schedule a meeting next week using the central
meeting reservation system, which is currently used at USC Leavey library.
Q.
Group I (Simple)
Q
1
. What is your preferred time range to start the meeting on each day of the week?
(Note: Consider your actual class and other meeting constraints while answering this.)
Q
2
. What locations do you prefer for your meeting among the rooms that you chosen?
For your information, the number in the parentheses indicates the maximum capacity
of each room. (Note: Answer this based on your past experience at USC library.)
On the previous page, you were asked about your preferred time and locations to
schedule meetings. Given your choice, please answer following questions.
Q
3
. If necessary, will you be able to provide more options in terms of time?
If so, for each day of the week, what will be your extended available time range
for your meeting? If you will not be able to provide additional options, please skip this.
(Note: Consider your actual class and other meeting constraints while answering this.)
Q
4
. Likewise, what additional locations would you consider for your meeting?
If you do not think you will be able to provide additional options, please skip this.
For your information, the number in the parentheses indicates the maximum capacity
of each room. (Note: Answer this based on your past experience at USC library.)
Group II (Complex)
Q
1
. What is your preferred time range to start the meeting on each day of the week?
(Note: Consider your actual class and other meeting constraints while answering this.)
Q
2
. What locations do you prefer for your meeting among the rooms that you chosen?
For your information, the number in the parentheses indicates the maximum capacity
of each room. (Note: Answer this based on your past experience at USC library.)
On the previous page, you were asked about your preferred time and locations to
schedule meetings. Given your choice, please answer following questions.
Q
3
. If necessary, will you be able to provide more options in terms of time?
If so, for each day of the week, what will be your extended available time range
for your meeting? If you will not be able to provide additional options, please skip this.
On average, people who are using this system give 3–4 hr range for their available
time on each day. This helps the system to compute more energy-ecient schedules
leading to energy savings by about 30% at USC Leavey library (about $5,765/year).
(Note: Consider your actual class and other meeting constraints while answering this.)
Q
4
. Likewise, what additional locations would you consider for your meeting?
If you will not be able to provide additional options, please skip this.
The number in the parentheses indicates the maximum capacity of each room.
On average, people who are using this system choose 5–6 rooms for their available
locations. This helps the system to compute more energy-ecient schedules that
lead to energy savings by about 20% at USC Leavey library (about $3,845/year).
(Note: Answer this based on your past experience at USC Leavey library.)
82
Table 4.9: Flexibility manipulation with various feedback (%)
Group I Group II
Average amount of flexibility change 5.15 17.12
83
Chapter 5: THINC
THINC is made up of three specific algorithms (as shown in Figure 5.1): (i) the scheduling
algorithm described in Chapter 4, (ii) novel approximation algorithms that eciently compute fair
individual allocations based on the Shapley value, and (iii) a new robust algorithm that reschedules
user meetings under uncertainty.
5.1 Fair Division of Credit
In my problem, users indicate their flexibility which determines their marginal contributions to the
total energy savings. Given the energy savings, the idea is to allocate some energy credit (e.g., a
Figure 5.1: THINC architecture
84
significant portion of the savings) to individual users. In allocating credit, equal allocation may not
be perceived as fair as shown in [Abrahmase et al., 2005; Hassett and Metcalf, 1995] and my survey
results (Section 5.3.1). Furthermore, proportional allocation based on flexibility fails in practice
because the amount of flexibility does not necessarily reflect users’ true contributions to energy
savings. For example, out of two users A and B, let A oer 80% flexibility late at night, while
B oers 40% flexibility during peak hours. Since B requests a meeting at a peak time/location
(where given individual flexibility can be jointly exploited with others for more energy savings,
e.g., back-to-back eect described in Section 4.2) and A at an o-peak time/location, flexibility of
B may lead to more energy savings as compared to A due to the exploitation of joint flexibility.
Therefore, flexibility of B has a greater eect in this case and hence B’s compensation should be
higher. If we used proportional allocation, A would get higher compensation which will not be
perceived as fair.
My energy-cost minimizing scheduling problem can be framed as a coalitional game, (N; v),
where:
N is a finite set of players, indexed by i. In my case, N indicates the set of meeting requests.
S is a coalition N. In my case, it is a subset of meeting requests that provide flexibility.
1
So a coalition is formed from meetings that provide flexibility.
v : 2
N
7! R is a characteristic function. In my case, v(S ) is the total energy-savings
obtained when requests in S are flexible and requests in Nn S are not flexible. Formally:
v(S ) = ˆ e(S ) e(S ), where e(S ) is the energy consumption when meeting requests in S
provide flexibility and ˆ e(S ) is the energy consumption when requests in S do not provide
1
This definition can be easily extended to the case where each separate coalition is defined based on a discretized
level of flexibility.
85
Figure 5.2: Illustrative example: L
i
& T
i
mean available rooms and time slots, respectively. Each meeting
request r
i
has a set of preferred locations and time, which indicates location and time flexibility.
flexibility, while requests in Nn S are held constant as not providing flexibility (i.e., requests
not providing flexibility are considered to be fixed to most preferred time/location as
determined by data collected on all meetings).
2
For this game, I appeal to the Shapley value [Shapley, 1953] solution concept for guidance on
how to fairly allocate credit. The Shapley value is computationally complex (2
n
2 O(v) for
each player), where O(v) is the complexity of the characteristic function [Shapley, 1953]. The
computational challenge for computing the Shapley value in THINC is actually two-fold. First,
computing the Shapley value for a single meeting request is challenging because we need to know
the marginal contribution to all possible coalitions (Equation (2.4)). Second, we need to solve
the MILP (Eq. (4.2)–(4.8) in Chapter 4) many times for computing the characteristic function
values, and it is dicult to scale up this computation to a large number of meeting requests. For
instance, as shown in Figure 5.2, let us assume that there are five meeting requests r
1
, r
2
, :::,
r
5
with flexibility. Even in this small example, to compute the exact Shapley value for each
meeting request, we are required to repeatedly compute v(S ) 64 (= 2
5
2) times in total, which is
computationally expensive. Given these diculties, I turn to approximation methods.
2
e(S ) is computed using the MILP in Section 4.2.
86
5.1.1 Approximate Shapley computation
I eciently approximate the Shapley value using: (i) sampling and (ii) graph partitioning.
Sampling: Random sampling can be used to approximate the Shapley value [Castro et al., 2009;
Fatima et al., 2008; Mann and Llyod, 1960; Owen, 1972]. In particular, Castro et al. [Castro
et al., 2009] presented the ApproShapley algorithm, a sampling mechanism for polynomial-
time approximation of the Shapley value. In ApproShapley, the characteristic function value is
repeatedly computed (m 2) times per each player, where m is the number of samples. In the
above example, for each meeting request, we now only need to compute v(S ) 20 (= 10 2) times
with 10 samples, which is smaller than the exact Shapley value computation.
Graph Partitioning: In addition to using ApproShapley, we can partition the entire meeting
request set into multiple independent subsets, which reduces the overall computational burden.
This idea is justified by the inessential axiom defined below. The entire meeting request set R can
be represented as an unweighted undirected graph denoted G = (V; E). As shown in Figure 5.2,
each vertex in V represents a meeting request in R. If the flexibility ranges of any two meeting
requests overlap, then those meeting requests are connected as an unordered pair in the graph
defining the edge set E (with edge weight defined by the amount of overlap). For example,
in Figure 5.2, r
2
and r
3
overlap, defining an edge between them. We can define a notion of
independence between two meeting request subsets R
m
and R
n
, where R
m
; R
n
R, as follows. Two
important technical lemmas then follow:
Definition 2. Independence: R
m
and R
n
are independent if e(R
m
[ R
n
) = e(R
m
) + e(R
n
), where
e(R) is the energy consumption of the given meeting request set R.
3
3
Please note that we need to run the MILP to test for independence.
87
Lemma 1. The characteristic function v for independent meetings in my coalitional game is
inessential [Hamiache, 2001].
Proof. (Sketch) Let us assume that two meeting request subsets R
1
and R
2
( R) are independent.
Recall that, in my problem, v(R) indicates energy savings caused by a joint flexibility in R: v(R) =
ˆ e(R) e(R). In addition, due to the independence between R
1
and R
2
, e(R
1
[ R
2
) = e(R
1
) + e(R
2
)
(i.e., satisfies the inessential property both with (e) and without flexibility (ˆ e)).
v(R
1
[ R
2
) = ˆ e(R
1
[ R
2
) e(R
1
[ R
2
)
= [ˆ e(R
1
) + ˆ e(R
2
)] [e(R
1
) + e(R
2
)] (* e; ˆ e: inessential)
= [ˆ e(R
1
) e(R
1
)] + [ˆ e(R
2
) e(R
2
)]
= v(R
1
) + v(R
2
):
Lemma 2. Assume that two meeting request subsets R
1
and R
2
( R) are independent. If meeting
request i is in R
1
, then the Shapley value satisfies:
i
(R
1
[ R
2
; v) =
i
(R
1
; v).
Proof. (Sketch) Let S = S
1
[ S
2
, where S
1
R
1
and S
2
R
2
. Since R
1
and R
2
satisfy
independence, S
1
and S
2
also hold the same property. Then, the equation (2.4) can be rewritten as
88
follows:
i
(R
1
[ R
2
; v) =
n1
X
s=0
s!(n 1 s)!
n!
8
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
:
X
S =S
1
[S
2
R
1
[R
2
nfig;jSj=s
v(S
1
[ S
2
[fig) v(S
1
[ S
2
)
9
>
>
>
=
>
>
>
;
=
n1
X
s=0
s!(n 1 s)!
n!
8
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
:
X
S =S
1
[S
2
R
1
[R
2
nfig;jSj=s
[v(S
1
[fig)+v(S
2
)][v(S
1
)+v(S
2
)]
9
>
>
>
=
>
>
>
;
(* the inessential property of v(R
1
[ R
2
) & S
1
[fig2 R
1
; S
2
2 R
2
)
=
n1
X
s=0
s!(n 1 s)!
n!
X
S =S
1
R
1
nfig;jSj=s
(v(S
1
[fig) v(S
1
))
=
i
(R
1
; v):
Based on these two properties, the graph G can be partitioned and the Shapley value for meet-
ings in each partition can be computed separately — thus partitioning can speed up computation
of Shapley value. Please note that only when there are non-overlapping meetings (i.e., complete
independence), we can partition without loss in accuracy of Shapley value, as shown in Lemma
2. However, as shown in Figure 5.2, if there are partitions that cut across an edge, some loss in
accuracy occurs; but we can minimize this loss by finding partitions that minimize the number of
edges cut. This trade-o in number of partitions and accuracy will be discussed in the evaluation
section.
89
5.1.2 Approximate characteristic value computation
In my work, the characteristic function, v(S ), itself is computationally intensive because it is an
MILP. To compute the Shapley value, we need to solve multiple instances of these MILPs. Thus, I
introduce ecient methods to approximate the characteristic value computation by relying on (i)
caching and (ii) LP relaxation.
Caching: This technique exploits the following property:
Definition 3. Exchangeability: v is exchangeable if, for every permutation of S N, v(S ) =
v((S )) [Aldous, 1985].
v(S ) in my problem is exchangeable. Thus, we can further speed up the Shapley value
computation by storing evaluations of v(S ). In this way, the characteristic function value of each
coalition and all its permutations is computed only once.
LP Relaxation: It is natural then to use MILP relaxation to approximately compute v(S ). I
specifically relax the integrality constraint (4.8) in (MILP) to 0 x
i;l;t
1 for getting a linear
program (LP). The optimal solution of (LP) is a lower bound on the optimal value of (MILP). I
empirically show the strength of the LP relaxation for my specific MILP in the evaluation section.
5.2 THINC Rescheduling Algorithm
While THINC performs energy-ecient scheduling, it may perceive that shifting some carefully
selected meetings can lead to significant energy savings. THINC then makes suggestions to
involved users on how to best reschedule their meetings while ensuring a balance between energy
savings and user comfort (hence, multi-objective MDP). We cannot know the exact likelihood
that users will comply with suggestions, and we may also be uncertain about the reward from
90
energy-savings and user comfort (hence the model uncertainty). I provide new algorithms for
BM-MDPs in THINC in addressing these challenges.
As a concrete example of how THINC can reschedule meetings, suppose two meeting requests
(r
1
and r
2
), which are originally scheduled in (10am, Room A) and (10am, Room B) respectively,
are identified for rescheduling. THINC’s policy may suggest r
1
and r
2
to be rescheduled to
dierent times but the same location as r
3
(12pm, Room B). This way, the agent can consolidate
all three meetings (r
1
– r
3
) together in a smaller room B which is less expensive to heat/cool.
Now, assuming that r
1
can only be scheduled either at 10am or 12pm, the best scenario is to
reschedule r
1
to (10am, Room B) and r
2
to (11am, Room B) so that all three meetings only use
Room B from 10am to 12pm, sequentially. Let us also assume that the r
2
is less likely to agree to
reschedule, and the likelihood of r
1
and r
3
is high. In this situation, if r
2
does not comply (given
low likelihood) then THINC’s computed policy needs to provide an alternative action given r
2
’s
refusal, while considering the likelihood of acceptance for this alternative. In particular, THINC
instead suggests rescheduling r
3
to (11am, Room B) and r
1
to (12pm, Room B), which is highly
likely to be accepted by users. In addition, if an unexpected new meeting request (r
4
) arrives and
is identified as an energy-consuming meeting to be rescheduled, then the rescheduling policy may
need to change.
I thus provide two novel algorithms in this work: (i) a robust multi-objective MDP algorithm
for solving BM-MDPs which allows for stochasticity in user response at planning time and (ii)
replanning methods to handle execution-time uncertainty (e.g., due to the arrival of r
4
). I first
discuss my robust multi-objective MDP algorithm. Earlier work [Kwak et al., 2012a] provides
“optimistic” or “pessimistic” heuristics to solve BM-MDPs, but without any performance guarantee.
Instead, my present robust BM-MDP can be solved exactly by finite horizon value iteration. First,
91
the robust optimal expected value is computed using the robust value iteration [Bagnell et al.,
2001] for each objective. Next, given an optimal robust value for each objective, the regret across
all objectives is computed. Lastly, a robust policy that minimizes the regret is chosen.
STEP I: Computing the robust optimal value for each objective: I denote the (finite) state
space (set of meeting requests) by S and the (finite) space of actions by A (i.e., the set of energy-
ecient meeting rescheduling suggestions by THINC). I fix a finite time horizonT =f0; 1;:::; Tg,
i.e., my work always uses a T period lookahead policy when (re)planning. Let I index a set
of reward functions r
i
: S A ! R to allow for multiple objectives. These include energy
eciency and comfort of dierent users. We let ( jjs; a) denote the transition probabilities, the
probability of transitioning to state j2 S given (s; a). For each state and action, we letR
i
(s; a)
denote the uncertainty set for reward r
i
, and we let (s; a) denote the uncertainty set for. The
uncertainty set defines possible realizations of the uncertain parameters, e.g., uncertainty set of
reward for comfort may be the interval say 1–5. For emphasis, both of these uncertainty sets
depend on the current state-action pair. We let =f (s; a)g
s; a
and R
i
=
n
R
i
(s; a)
o
s; a
be the
collections of these uncertainty sets. For fixed i2 I, I want to maximize the worst-case reward,
i.e., max
a2A
min
2; r
i
2R
iE
h
P
T
t=0
t
r
i
(s
t
)
i
; whereE
[] explicitly indicates the dependence on the
transition probabilities and the policy, and s
t
is the state at time t. Because the uncertainty sets
only depend on the current state-action pair, the Bellman equation for the above robust MDP can
be written as follows:
V
i
t
(s) = max
a2A
min
2(s;a); r
i
2R
i
(s;a)
8
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
:
r
i
(s)+
X
j2S
( jjs; a) V
i
t+1
( j)
9
>
>
>
=
>
>
>
;
92
where V
i
t
is the time t value function. The values
n
V
i
t
(s)
o
s2S; t2T
can be computed through maximin
value iteration since we have a finite time horizon [Bagnell et al., 2001].
STEP II: Computing the regret across all objectives: Because my problem is multi-objective,
I want a policy that accounts for all objectives i2 I. So, I introduce a notion of regret that
accounts for all objectives. I will use a vector-valued value functionfW
t
g
t2T
R
jIj
where W
t
(s) =
W
i
t
(s)
i2I
;8t2T. For a given policy (which is dierent from the policy that computed V
i
t
in
Step I), the quantity
max
i2I
min
2(s;a); r
i
2R
i
(s;a)
8
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
:
r
i
(s)+
X
j2S
( jjs; a) W
i
t+1
( j)V
i
t
(s)
9
>
>
>
=
>
>
>
;
is the regret at time t in state s2 S for action a, where V
i
t
for each objective i is given as a constant
from Step I. Notice that this definition takes the minimum over all reward functions. The quantity
r
i
(s) +
P
j2S
( jjs; a) W
i
t+1
( j) is the value for objective i, and V
i
t
(s) is the optimal value for
objective i.
STEP III: Choosing the robust policy that minimizes the regret: In state s at time t I choose
a regret minimizing action
t
(s)2 arg min
a2A
max
i2I
min
2(s;a); r
i
2R
i
(s;a)
8
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
:
r
i
(s) +
X
j2S
( jjs; a) W
i
t+1
( j) V
i
t
(s)
9
>
>
>
=
>
>
>
;
and then I set
W
i
t
(s) = min
2(s;
t
(s)); r2R
i
(s;
t
(s))
8
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
:
r
i
(s) +
X
j2S
jjs;
t
(s)
W
i
t+1
( j)
9
>
>
>
=
>
>
>
;
; (8s2 S;8i2 I):
93
The optimal action is chosen in consideration of all objectives i2 I, and then each component of
W
t
is updated separately assuming the same optimal action is taken in each update. The resulting
policy
=
t
t2T
is the optimal regret minimizing policy.
During the execution of such a policy, THINC sometimes encounters unexpected situations,
e.g., in the example above r
4
arrived when it was not part of the initial BM-MDP state-space and
was an energy-consuming meeting in need of rescheduling. THINC’s key insight is to continue
to use the current BM-MDP policy to the extent possible, replanning only when new meetings
are seen to potentially interfere with that policy. One alternative approach is to avoid BM-MDP
planning altogether and only react to the current state. Another alternative is to stay completely
committed to the original policy until completion while ignoring the new meetings. THINC rejects
both of these extreme approaches and occupies a middle ground: it does use a BM-MDP policy,
but when new meetings arrive, it checks if they interfere with the current policy. Specifically, the
majority of incoming meeting requests propose locations and times that do not aect the current
policy, allowing THINC to accrue the benefits of its optimal planning (carried out to completion)
in majority of cases; but THINC will occasionally compute a new policy if the new meetings are
seen to potentially interfere. Using real meeting arrival data in a large university building, THINC
demonstrates that this “middle-ground” approach outperforms the two extreme approaches in my
domain (Section 5.3.2).
5.3 Empirical Validation
I evaluate THINC in this section. For the evaluation, I built upon the simulation testbed developed
in [Kwak et al., 2012a] by using a large data set of real meeting requests and building statistics
94
collected from the testbed building. For experiments with meetings, I selected data from the library,
where 100 meetings may arrive per day. The experiments were run on Intel Core2 Duo 2.53GHz
CPU with 8GB memory. I solved MILPs using CPLEX version 12.1. I ran all algorithms for 100
independent trials and report average values.
5.3.1 Shapley Value Evaluation
5.3.1.1 Fair Division: Why Shapley Value?
The Shapley value gives a theoretically fair allocation and has been previously applied in energy
domains [Alam et al., 2013; Stein et al., 2012]. However, I wished to check user reactions in my
own domain, i.e., whether people believe that the Shapley value produces fair allocations of energy
credits. So, I launched a survey on Amazon Mechanical Turk (AMT) and collected data for 53
unique samples. I showed survey participants two dierent allocations: one based on Shapley
value and the other based on equal division. I then asked survey participants to rate fairness of
each allocation scheme on a scale of 1 to 7 while varying information, where 7 indicates high
fairness. I found that people perceive Shapley value based allocations to be more fair than those
based on equal division. The average fairness rating over all users for Shapley based allocation is
5.2, as compared to 3.6 for equal division and this result is statistically significant (paired t-test; p
0.04).
5.3.1.2 Approximation
We already know that the Shapley value is computationally expensive for the setting used in my
work. As shown in Figure 5.3 for the illustration purpose, as the number of meetings (x-axis)
increases from 5 to 100, the average runtime (y-axis) of the Shapley value computation increases
95
Figure 5.3: Runtime comparison – S: Sampling (# of samples), C: Caching, P: Partitioning (# of
partitions), L: LP Relaxation
Table 5.1: Runtime Comparison (hours) – In conjunction with caching & LP relaxation (# of meetings:
100)
h
h
h
h
h
h
h
h
h
h
h
h
h
h
h
h h
# of samples
# of partitions
5 10 20
20 0.19 0.07 0.04
50 0.49 0.17 0.11
100 0.97 0.33 0.20
exponentially — in fact the computation was not completed within a reasonable amount of time.
As shown in the figure, the overall runtime could be significantly improved (sped up by orders of
magnitude) by combining my approximation methods.
As I provide a set of dierent Shapley approximation algorithms, it is essential to understand
the contribution of dierent combinations of my approximation methods. In particular, it is
important to derive settings that would allow the right tradeo between solution quality and
eciency for my actual setting involving 100 meeting inputs per day. I thus evaluated potential
speed-up by using graph partitioning on top of ApproShapley in conjunction with caching and LP
relaxation. To perform graph partitioning, my work relied on the METIS library
4
, an open-source
4
http://glaros.dtc.umn.edu/gkhome/views/metis
96
Figure 5.4: Solution quality Figure 5.5: Average deviation (%)
library for partitioning graphs based on the multilevel recursive-bisection and multi-constraint
partitioning schemes. I tested the performance of my approximation algorithms using real meeting
data while varying the number of samples and partitions. Table 5.1 shows the average runtime
when a large number of meeting requests are given (100). Even with a large number of meeting
requests, I was able to complete the overall computation in a timely fashion.
I next investigated the solution quality while keeping the same condition that was used during
the runtime comparison. Figure 5.4 plots the average error (i.e., the average relative variance)
(y-axis) against the number of partitions (5–20; x-axis) with a fixed number of samples (100) for
ApproShapley.We see that as the number of partitions increases, the overall runtime decreases
(Table 5.1) while the average error increases (Figure 5.4). I conclude that the combination of 100
samples and 5 partitions provides a reasonable solution (about 10% error) in a timely fashion
(within 1 hour) when a large number of meeting requests arrive.
So far, I analyzed two dierent layers of approximations presented in my work. The question
now is that how close my approximate solutions are to the true Shapley value with dierent
combinations of these approximations. Thus, I measured the average deviation of a combination
97
Figure 5.6: Eciency violation (%) Figure 5.7: Solution quality
of my approximation algorithms (i.e., sampling, caching with partitioning using 20 samples and 2
partitions;
20;2
S CP
) from the exact Shapley value (
S
). I conducted this experiment on 20 sampled
days selecting 5 meetings per day, from real meeting data. I used a small number of meetings (5)
in this test as the exact Shapley value cannot scale up beyond that.
Figure 5.5 shows the average deviation of
20;2
S CP
in percentage (y-axis) on 20 sampled days
(x-axis). As shown in the figure, my approximation method generally followed the exact Shapley
allocations, and the average deviation of
20
S C
from
S
was 7.73% (6.18–9.43%), which was fairly
small.
It is important to verify that my approximation methods are still able to generate solutions close
to theoretically fair allocations even when the problem size increases. Given the limited scalability
of Shapley value, I instead focus on showing what properties out of the four that axiomatize
fairness in the Shapley value are satisfied by my approximations. My approximate allocations
automatically satisfy the additivity and dummy player properties, but they do not always guarantee
satisfaction of the eciency and symmetry properties.
5
We can test empirically how often my
approximation algorithms violate the eciency and symmetry properties.
5
The formal proof is provided in Appendix A.
98
Figure 5.6 shows the likelihood that allocations computed from a graph partitions violate
eciency (in percentage) on the y-axis while varying the number of partitions on the x-axis.
Intuitively, as the number of partitions increases, the likelihood that the eciency property is
violated also increases. However, the overall likelihood was still less than 8%. In particular, when
5 partitions are used, the likelihood was less than 3%. With respect to the symmetry, the maximum
violation rate was less than 9.2% when the number of partitions varied from 0 to 20. These results
show that my allocations approximately satisfy the properties that axiomatize fairness.
5.3.2 Performance of replanning BM-MDP
In this section, I first tested if my robust multi-objective MDP algorithm that solves BM-MDPs
could generate robust well-balanced solutions (i.e., lower average regret) as compared to the
standard MDP with a unified reward based on the weighted sum method and the average model
from uncertainty sets, and the pessimistic heuristic for solving BM-MDPs [Kwak et al., 2012a].
The uniform weight distribution was applied to the weighted sum method. 50 dierent instances
were used.
6
Each problem is based on real meeting data. On average, the MDP showed the
worst result among three (2.13 times higher regret than my method) and the pessimistic heuristic
achieved 1.19 times higher regret than mine, which clearly shows that my method is even more
robust than the best known algorithm for solving BM-MDPs.
I then evaluated the performance of the replanning BM-MDP against three approaches while
rescheduling meetings under uncertainty at both planning and execution time: (i) full-online
replanning: it chooses the local best action at every time point (i.e., greedy approach), (ii)
full-oine BM-MDP: it commits to the original policy until completion while ignoring the
6
I generate dierent problem instances while varying the level of uncertainty (0–100%).
99
(a) Time flexibility (b) Location flexibility
Figure 5.8: Measured users’ flexibility
new meetings, and (iii) TESLA [Kwak et al., 2013a] that assumes users would always agree
to reschedule their meetings. I compared these four approaches on 100 dierent instances in
simulation and reported the average performance.
Figure 5.7 shows the normalized performance (y-axis) of each algorithm compared to the aver-
age regret achieved by THINC’s MDP. As the figure shows, the oine BM-MDP achieved about
1.38 times higher regret as compared to the replanning MDP performance, and the reactive strategy
achieved about 1.63 times higher regret. TESLA showed the worst result (i.e., highest average
regret), and it can be arbitrarily bad as it does not consider any uncertainty while rescheduling user
meetings. My replanning BM-MDP strategy is most robust as compared to the others.
5.3.3 Deployed Application
I deployed my integrated agent THINC as a pilot project at the Doheny library at the University of
Southern California. The objective of this deployment is to test the performance of THINC in this
smaller building first before deploying it at a much bigger building where there are indeed hundreds
of meetings per day. 45 students used THINC during the pilot deployment. Figure 5.8 shows the
100
Table 5.2: Rescheduling real meetings: uncertainty in user reactions
% of no-response % of rejection
First suggestion 35.0 48.0
Second suggestion 26.5 40.5
Third suggestion 20.7 39.8
students’ reported time and location flexibility. The x-axis shows the discretized flexibility level
and the corresponding frequency is reported on the y-axis. Participants reported varying levels of
time and location flexibility. The average time flexibility was 27.05%, and time flexibility ranged
between 0.0% and 68.18%. The average location flexibility was 42.48%, and location flexibility
ranged from 0.0 to 100.0%. This shows that, in practice, people are willing to provide a reasonable
amount of flexibility allowing significant energy savings.
As part of the pilot deployment, I identified 20 key meeting requests for rescheduling. THINC’s
BM-MDP policy suggested dierent slots (i.e., a pair of time and location) every 6 hours. As
shown in Table 5.2, the measured uncertainty while interacting with users for rescheduling their
meetings was significant, which emphasizes that previous work [Kwak et al., 2013a] cannot
be applied in real situations. On average, my work achieved the compliance rate of 45% for
successfully rescheduling them with 3.6 interactions per user. This result clearly shows that
BM-MDP for rescheduling identified key meetings is useful rather than simply assuming users
will blindly accept every suggestion.
I then divide a portion of energy savings based on the Shapley value. To test if the users of
THINC perceived my credit allocation scheme to be fair, I asked the same participants to rate
fairness and their willingness to participate in energy savings on a scale of 1 to 7, where 7 denotes
a high rating for fairness and willingness to participate. The average fairness rating is 5.24 and
the average willingness to participate rating is 6.0. Thus we can see that users of the system
101
perceive the Shapley based allocation scheme to be highly fair. This average fairness rating is also
consistent with the result from the AMT survey, which further supports the use of Shapley value
as a fair allocation method.
102
Chapter 6: Related Work
Recent years have seen a rise of interest in the development of multiagent systems in energy
domains that inherently have uncertain and dynamic environments with limited resources. In
discussing related work, a key point I wish to emphasize is the uniqueness of my work [Kwak
et al., 2012a,b, 2013a,b] in combining research on multiagent systems, specifically (i) fair division
of credit for energy savings in the context of cooperative game theory; (ii) robust MDP algorithms
that handle multi-objective optimization under uncertainty; and (iii) comfort-based energy-ecient
incremental scheduling in an innovative application for energy savings. It is this specific combi-
nation of attributes that sets my work apart from previous research. Furthermore, a key novelty
as an agent-based system for energy savings is that, my work is evaluated on real building and
meeting/event data that have been collected from more than 500 rooms in ten educational buildings
at USC and SMU.
In this chapter, I will describe research related to my thesis in the following categories: (i)
agent-based systems in energy, (ii) robust MDP and multi-objective techniques, (iii) resource
allocation and scheduling, (iv) fair division in cooperative game theory, and (v) social influence in
human subject studies.
103
6.1 Agent-based Systems in Energy
Agent-based systems have been considered to provide sustainable energy for smart grid manage-
ment. Chalkiadakis et al. [Chalkiadakis et al., 2011] suggested Cooperative Virtual Power Plants
(CVPPs) for achieving the cost-ecient integration of the many distributed energy resources by
relying on a game-theoretic approach. V oice et al. [V oice et al., 2011] provided a game-theoretic
framework for modeling storage devices in large-scale systems where each storage device is owned
by a self-interested agent that aims to maximize its monetary profit. In addition, [Kamboj et al.,
2011] addressed research challenges to integrate plug-in Electric Vehicles (EVs) into the smart
grid. Stein et al. [Stein et al., 2012] also introduced a novel online mechanism that schedules the
allocation of an expiring and continuously-produced resource to self-interested agents with private
preferences while focusing on the fairness using pre-commitment in smart grid domain, which
is not directly applicable in commercial buildings. Miller et al. [Miller et al., 2012] investigated
how the optimal dispatch problem in the smart grid can be framed as a decentralized agent-based
coordination problem and presented a novel decentralized message passing algorithm. Their work
was empirically evaluated in large networks using real distribution network data.
The rise in energy consumption in buildings can be attributed to several factors such as
enhancement of building services and comfort levels [Gao et al., 2010; Perez-Lombard et al.,
2008; Santamouris et al., 1994; Sun and Lee, 2006]. To model and optimize building energy
consumption, Ramchurn et al. [Ramchurn et al., 2011] considered more complex deferrable loads
and managing comfort in the residential buildings. Rogers et al. [Rogers et al., 2011] addressed the
challenge of adaptively controlling a home heating system in order to minimize cost and carbon
emissions within a smart grid using Gaussian processes to predict the environmental parameters.
104
Abras et al. [Abras et al., 2006], Conte et al. [Conte and Scaradozzi, 2003] and Roy et al. [Roy
et al., 2006] have employed multiagent systems to model home automation systems (or smart
homes) and simulating control algorithms to evaluate performance. More recently, Mamidi et
al. [Mamidi et al., 2012b] conducted research on smart sensing and adaptive energy management
system in commercial buildings. They implemented a multi-model sensor agent using various
types of sensors to estimate the number of occupants in each room and predict future occupancy
using machine learning techniques. This prediction can be potentially used for ecient HA VC
operations in the building. Jazizadeh et al. [Jazizadeh et al., 2013a,b] recently focused on building
a human-building interaction framework for understanding personalized thermal comfort models
in oce buildings. Research by Li et al. [Li et al., 2012a,b] focused on understanding building
occupancy with RFID on hand-held devices and demand-driven HA VC operations based on the
measured occupancy. My work is dierent in focusing on energy savings in commercial buildings
by relying on dierent representation and approaches from previous work, which allows consumers
(i.e., occupants) to play a part in optimizing the operation in the building instead of managing the
optimal demand on buildings.
6.2 Robust MDP and Multi-objective Optimization Techniques
There has been a significant amount of work done on multi-objective optimization. Stadler and
Dauer [Stadler, 1987, 1988; Stadler and Dauer, 1992] provide extensive discussions on the funda-
mental concepts and ideas in this field. In contrast to single-objective optimization, there is no
single global solution while optimizing the multiple criteria, and the most predominant concept in
defining optimal solutions is Pareto Optimality [Pareto, 1906]. Vincent and Grantham [Vincent
105
and Grantham, 1981] and Miettinen [Miettinen, 1999] have been discussing theoretical necessary
and sucient conditions to formally qualify Pareto Optimality. As alternative to the idea, Saluk-
vadze [Salukvadze, 1971a,b] also proposed a compromised solution concept, which generates a
single solution.
In terms of solution methods, The most common approaches to multi-objective optimization are
to find Pareto optimal solutions by using the weighted sum method to aggregate multiple objectives
using a prior preference [Yoon and Hwang, 1995] or by considering the weighted min-max (or
Tchebyche ) formulation that provides a nice theoretical property in terms of sucient/necessary
conditions for Pareto optimality [Koski and Silvennoinen, 1987; Messac et al., 2000a,b; Miettinen,
1999]. It has been proven that if all weight values are positive, this method gives Pareto optimal
solutions [Zadeh, 1963]. However, previous research [Athan and Papalambros, 1996; Das and
Dennis, 1997; Koski, 1985; Messac et al., 2000a,b; Stadler, 1995] discuss about weaknesses of this
method. Despite all these limitations, I use this method as a benchmark method for comparison
purposes since it is still widely used in this field.
Chatterjee et al. [Chatterjee et al., 2006] considered MDPs with multiple discounted reward
objectives. They theoretically analyzed the complexity of the proposed approach and showed that
the Pareto curve can be approximated in polynomial time. Wiering and Jong [Wiering and De Jong,
2007] described a novel algorithm to compute Pareto optimal policies for deterministic multi-
objective sequential decision problems. Authors proved that the algorithm converges to the Pareto
optimal set of value functions and policies for deterministic infinite horizon discounted multi-
objective Markov decision problems. Ogryczak et al. [Ogryczak et al., 2011] focused on finding a
compromise solution in multi-objective MDPs for a well-balanced solution. They compared their
approach relying on the Tchebyche scalarizing function to the weighted sum method. On the
106
other hand, there has been some significant advances to handle model uncertainty on standard
MDPs including [Delgado et al., 2009; Givan et al., 2000]. Recently, Soh and Demiris [Soh and
Demiris, 2011] extended the previous work and considered the multiple-reward POMDPs. They
presented two hybrid multi-objective evolutionary algorithms that generate non-dominated sets
of policies. My work is dierent from them as I assume model uncertainty while simultaneously
optimizing multiple criteria in MDPs.
6.3 Resource Allocation and Scheduling
There has been some work focusing on scheduling of home appliances considering user pref-
erences [Bapat et al., 2011; Sou et al., 2011; Xiong et al., 2011]. In particular, they consider
inferred user’s preferred usage profile while scheduling home appliances in residential buildings,
which is considered as a fixed constraint. My work is dierent as it does not only maximize
energy savings while considering users’ preferences, but also eectively interacts with users to
change their flexibility to achieve further energy savings. More recently, there has been some
work focusing on energy-aware scheduling in commercial buildings [Majumdar et al., 2012]. The
authors only consider the HV AC systems and ignore other significant energy consumers such as
lighting and electronics in commercial buildings while optimizing schedules based on the given
fixed constraints. My thesis work is dierent by focusing on an energy-oriented scheduling while
considering major energy consumers (HV ACs, lighting and electronics) together in commercial
buildings. I also identify key meetings for flexibility change, an aspect that is missing in this
previous work.
107
In a multiagent community, there has been a significant amount of work that has focused
on meeting/event scheduling based on the distributed constraint optimization (DCOP) formu-
lation [Maheswaran et al., 2004; Sultanik et al., 2007]. They provide distributed scheduling
frameworks that are limited to dynamic scheduling problems. In addition, they focused on schedul-
ing meetings without energy considerations. My work diers from their work as it explicitly
aims to conserve energy while scheduling incrementally/dynamically arriving requests. Wainer et
al. [Wainer et al., 2007] also presented a set of protocols for scheduling a meeting among agents
that represent their respective user’s interests and evaluated the suggested protocols while handling
meeting scheduling problems. The objective in their work is to find the optimal protocol to reach
agreement among agents, which does not explicitly account for energy.
Online scheduling techniques have been investigated to handle incremental requests consid-
ering temporal flexibility [Gallagher et al., 2006; Policella et al., 2004]. My work is dierent by
focusing on energy-oriented scheduling in commercial buildings while allowing people to play a
part in optimizing the operation in the building.
6.4 Fair Division in Cooperative Game Theory
6.4.1 Cooperative Game Theory in Energy Systems
Alam et al. [Alam et al., 2013] investigated the exchange of energy between homes in a community
to reduce the overall battery usage, and showed that agents (acting on the behalf of households)
can coordinate and regulate the exchange of energy between homes which leads to two surpluses:
reduction in the overall battery usage and reduction in the energy losses. To ensure a fair distri-
bution of these surpluses among agents, each agent’s contribution to both surpluses is computed
108
using the Shapley value and an approximation method is used to speed up this computation. Khan
et al. [Khan and Ahmad, 2009] applied the concept of Nash Bargaining Solution (NBS) from co-
operative game theory to minimize energy consumption and response time in computational grids
and showed that the solution is guaranteed to be Pareto-optimal. Zima et al. [Zima-Bockarjova
et al., 2010b] apply cooperative game theoretic concepts to the problem of energy supply system
planning to maximize profit earned by market participants. They find the Shapley value for each
agent to divide additional gains among the coalition participants. Sereno [Sereno, 2012] used
cooperative game theory to develop a framework for energy-aware policies in cellular networks.
[Sereno, 2012] also discusses fair division of benefits derived from cooperating agents based
on the Shapley value solution concept. [Kattuman et al., 2001; Hsieh, 2006; Zima-Bockarjova
et al., 2010a] also discuss the application of Shapley value to solve the loss allocation problem in
electricity markets and for sharing of profit obtained from coordinated operation in hydro and wind
power production domains. My work is dierent in that it provides an integrated agent that focuses
on fair credit allocations, based on novel ecient Shapley value computation while exploiting the
domain properties. This is for incentivizing users to participate in this energy saving process in
commercial buildings.
6.4.2 Shapley Value and Approximation Techniques
[Bachrach et al., 2013] focuses on showing how various cooperative game-theoretic solution
concepts can be used in a network connectivity scenario (particularly network communication
reliability domain). In particular, they investigated Shapley value, Banzhaf power indices, the
core and the epsilon core. This paper includes a good amount of literature review and polynomial
algorithms for the restricted domain where the graph has a tree structure. Although I construct a
109
flexibility-based influence graph, which is similar to a connectivity graph used in this work, I use a
given general graph mainly for speeding up the computation by considering partitions.
Various methods of approximating the Shapley value can be found in literature. Mann et
al. [Mann and Llyod, 1960] proposed a Monte-Carlo simulation technique for approximating the
Shapley value and applied it to analyze the US electoral-voting system. Owen’s [Owen, 1972]
multilinear extension method for approximating the Shapley value in weighted voting games is
linear in the number of players. Fatima et al. [Fatima et al., 2008] also provided an approximation
method for the Shapley value which is linear in the number of players for k-majority games.
However, the approximation error for their method was relatively low as compared to Owen’s.
They also empirically evaluated the approximation error and analyzed how various parameters of
a voting game, like the number of players and the quota, aect the error. Aadithya et al. [Aadithya
et al., 2010] explored ecient ways of calculating the Shapley value for network centralities.
Besides deriving closed-form expressions for the Shapley values based on the underlying network
structure and the game defined over the network, they also provide exact and polynomial time
Shapley value approximation algorithms based on them. Bachrach et al. [Bachrach et al., 2010]
includes a thorough literature survey of methods to approximate power indices such as the Banzhaf
and Shapley-Shubik power indices. They also suggest and analyze approximation algorithms for
these power indices and provide lower bounds for both deterministic and randomized algorithms
to calculate these indices. They also noted that the Shapley-Shubik power index approximation
method suggested in [Bachrach et al., 2010] can be adapted to eciently compute the Shapley
value by using proper bounds for the Hoeding inequality and thus use it to compute an individual’s
relative contribution to the IQ of a group in [Bachrach et al., 2012]. My approximation technique is
dierent from previous work as I exploit domain properties to integrate a novel graph partitioning
110
algorithm, caching technique, and an LP relaxation method to approximate the Shapley value and
simultaneously speed up its computation. In addition, my work integrates this technique within an
agent that (re)schedules meetings.
6.5 Social Influence in Human Subject Studies
I leverage lessons and insights from social psychology in understanding and designing reliable
and accurate human behavior models to compute robust strategies in the real-world. Wood and
Neal [Wood and Neal, 2007, 2009] have studied the potential of interventions to reduce energy
consumption and they have shown that it is not only to change workplace energy consumption
but also to establish energy use habits that maintain over time. Abrahmase et al. [Abrahmase
et al., 2005] reviewed 38 interventions aimed to reduce household energy consumption, and
they showed that information campaigns often improve knowledge but have limited influence
on behavior or energy savings in residential buildings. According to their study, when monetary
rewards were given for energy savings, energy consumption decreased in the short-run but not in
the longer-term after the rewards were terminated, and they concluded that normative feedback
about energy use is the most promising strategy for reducing and maintaining low consumption.
However, it focused on residential environments, which is dierent from my work. In a recent
study, Carrico and Riemer [Carrico and Riemer, 2011] provided monthly normative feedback via
email to occupants of a commercial building about their own buildings’ energy use in comparison
with and other, similar buildings. Unfortunately, the study only relied on self-reporting to assess
the behaviors. Instead, my work relies on both real sensors to observe their energy behavior in
real-time and self-reporting. Faruqui et al. [Faruqui et al., 2010] reviewed past experiments and
111
pilot projects to evaluate the eect of in-home displays (IHDs) on energy consumption. My work
is dierent because I simultaneously consider multiple criteria including energy consumption and
occupant comfort level. Research by Fahrioglu et al. [Fahrioglu and Alvardo, 2000], Mohsenian-
Rad et al. [Mohsenian-Rad et al., 2010] and Caron et al. [Caron and Kesidis, 2010] provide
incentive compatible mechanisms for distribution of energy among interested parties. This thread
of research is complementary, especially in designing incentives for humans to reveal their true
energy preferences. However, these approaches assume a centralized controller with whom all the
members interact, which is not present in my domain. Instead, there are peer-to-peer negotiations
between humans regarding their energy consumption and comfort level.
In social psychology, there has been a significant deal of work to figure out the correlation
between irritation/distraction factors and persuasion. McCullough and Ostrom [McCullough and
Ostrom, 1974], Cacioppo and Petty [Cacioppo and Petty, 1989] and Nordhielm [Nordhielm, 2002]
discussed that message repetition would increase positive attitudes in a situation where highly
similar communications are used and showed that there is a positive relationship between the
number of presentations and attitude from general social psychology perspectives. Focusing on a
commercial advertisement, Pechmann and Stewart [Pechmann and Stewart, 1988], Schumann et
al. [Schumann et al., 1990] and Calder and Sternthal [Calder and Sternthal, 1980] predicted the
eectiveness of dierent strategies on advertising and examined the eects of message repetition
on attitude changes. In addition, Baron et al. [Baron et al., 1973], Bither [Bither, 1972] and Regan
and Cheng [Regan and Cheng, 1973] discussed that distractions aect behavior decisions, but
they are more or less eective in increasing persuasion depending upon whether people can easily
ignore the distraction.
112
Chapter 7: Conclusions
The rapid growth in energy usage has made the need for systems that aid in reducing energy
consumption a top priority. To that end, researchers in multiagent community have been developing
multiagent systems to conserve energy for deployment in the smart grid and buildings [Kamboj
et al., 2011; Mamidi et al., 2012a; Miller et al., 2012; Ramchurn et al., 2011; Rogers et al., 2011;
Gerding et al., 2011; Chalkiadakis et al., 2011; V oice et al., 2011]. Despite the recent success to
forge a new area of agent-based systems for energy conservation, their work has been done with a
particular focus on residential buildings, and does not directly apply to commercial buildings. For
successfully developing real-world energy systems to conserve energy in commercial buildings,
three unique research challenges should be simultaneously addressed. First, algorithms should
be able to handle massive meetings/events schedules while focusing on conserving energy and
considering the given human models. Second, there are dierent types of energy-related behaviors
in commercial buildings from residential ones. They require agents to negotiate with groups of
people for guiding their behaviors to conserve energy while ensuring a balance of energy savings
and comfort under uncertainty over people’s behavior preferences. Third, the systems should
also ensure that proper credit is given based on people’s true contribution in energy savings for
eectively motivating people.
113
Given the huge growth of recent research interest at the intersection between computer science,
civil engineering, social psychology, architecture, and facility management, my thesis focused
on presenting new agent-based models and algorithms aiming to conserve energy in commercial
buildings. My thesis, specifically, contributed along two dimensions. Firstly, I developed new
models and algorithms to address the combinations of research challenges described above and to
provide robust solutions for such real-world problems. Secondly, my thesis also integrated novel
models and algorithms within agents dedicated to energy eciency.
7.1 Contributions
My thesis handled online predictive scheduling of massive numbers of dynamically arriving
and uncertain meetings/events while considering flexibility, which is a novel concept for
capturing generic user constraints. More specifically, I provided the following algorithmic
contribution: a two-stage stochastic mixed integer linear program (SMILP) for energy-
ecient scheduling of incrementally/dynamically arriving meetings and events. I compared
the simulation results in energy savings achieved by the proposed predictive scheduling
algorithm against real-world data. These results showed that my predictive scheduling
algorithms could potentially oer significant saving benefits in general scheduling domains
where schedule flexibility plays a key role for such savings.
My thesis provided a robust MDP (Markov Decision Problem) model and algorithms to
eectively reschedule group activities such as meetings/events for saving energy while
considering multiple objectives as well as uncertainty both at planning and execution time.
Specifically, I presented a novel model and robust algorithms:
114
– BM-MDP (Bounded-parameter Multi-objective MDP) that explicitly models multiple
criteria as well as uncertainty over people’s preferences
– robust algorithms to solve BM-MDPs and dynamic replanning methods for handling
uncertainty at execution time
I showed that BM-MDPs with replanning generated robust solutions while considering
multiple criteria and model uncertainty at both planning and execution time.
My thesis addressed fair division of credit using concepts of cooperative game theory. In
particular, I appealed to cooperative game theory and specifically to the concept of Shapley
value for this fair division. Unfortunately, scaling up this Shapley value computation is a
major hindrance in practice. Therefore, I presented a novel algorithmic contribution for
scaling up the overall computations:
– approximation algorithms to eciently compute the Shapley value based on sampling
and partitions
– an LP (linear program) relaxation method to speed up the characteristic function
computation
These approximations allowed ecient computations of fair individual allocations in a
large-scale saving game in the real-world. I also showed that dierent combinations of these
approximations can be chosen under particular circumstances while considering the tradeo
between solution quality and runtime.
My algorithmic contributions have been successfully integrated within agents dedicated to
energy eciency: SA VES, TESLA and THINC. SA VES provided several key novelties:
115
– jointly performed with the university facility management team, SA VES was based on
actual occupant preferences and schedules, actual energy consumption and loss data,
real sensors and hand-held devices, etc.
– it addressed novel scenarios that require negotiations with groups of building occupants
to conserve energy.
– it focused on a non-residential building, which requires a dierent mechanism to
eectively motivate occupants.
– SA VES used a novel algorithm for generating optimal MDP policies that explicitly
consider multiple criteria optimization as well as uncertainty over occupant preferences
when negotiating energy reduction.
I showed that SA VES substantially reduced the overall energy consumption compared to
the existing control method while achieving comparable average satisfaction levels for
occupants. Next, TESLA provided two key contributions:
– it presented online scheduling algorithms, which are at the heart of TESLA, to solve a
stochastic mixed integer linear program (SMILP) for energy-ecient scheduling of
incrementally/dynamically arriving meetings and events.
– it included an algorithm to eectively identify key meetings that lead to significant
energy savings by adjusting their flexibility.
Lastly, THINC provided two key contributions:
– it used novel algorithmic advances for ecient computation of Shapley value.
116
– it included a novel robust algorithm to optimally reschedule identified key meetings
addressing user interaction uncertainty.
TESLA and THINC were evaluated on data gathered from over 110,000 meetings held at
nine campus buildings during an eight month period in 2011–2012 at USC and SMU. These
results and analysis showed that, compared to the current systems, they could substantially
reduce overall energy consumption. In addition, Finally, THINC was deployed in the real-
world as a pilot project at the Doheny library at USC and presented results illustrating the
benefits in saving energy.
7.2 Future Work
As described in the earlier section, my work provided three key algorithmic contributions in-
cluding (i) energy-ecient scheduling of user meeting requests while considering flexibility, (ii)
rescheduling of key energy-consuming meetings for more energy savings, and (iii) ecient fair
credit allocations based on Shapley value to incentivize users for their energy saving activities.
These new models and methods have not only advanced the state of the art in multiagent algo-
rithms, but have actually been successfully integrated within agents dedicated to energy eciency,
clearly demonstrating the potential of agent technology to assist human users in saving energy in
commercial buildings.
However, there exist some remaining open challenges which can be explored for building
real-world energy applications going forward:
My present dynamic replanning MDP methods provide a reasonable way to handle uncer-
tainty both at planning and execution time; however, the further investigation regarding the
117
trigger points deciding when to keep the existing policy or when to regenerate the policy
from the scratch.
Scalability could be further investigated to further speed up the characteristic function
computation by adopting the decomposition methods such as a Lagrangian decomposition.
Although real building data of the Leavey library including the actual floor flan, lighting
specifications, etc., were used, the energy consumption validation on the library building
has not been thoroughly conducted in the simulation environment.
1
In practice, it is challenging to know the exact human behavior models while interacting
with users to reschedule their activities under dierent circumstances. So far, in this work, I
relied on sparse samples from surveys (conducted in RGL and Amazon Mechanical Turk
(AMT)) to construct the behavior models and applied the same models to dierent buildings
(e.g., Leavey and Doheny libraries), which results in potential noises on results.
Human subject experiments were conducted in a limited fashion:
– AMT, which I have used for conducting human subject experiments, is limited to
provide participants with the exact context in detail as it often assumes hypothetical
situations which might not be realized in practice.
– The human subject experiments conducted at USC with sta and students relied upon
self-reports which may not reflect actual circumstances, and long-term eects were
not observed.
1
The energy consumption validation has been thoroughly performed on the RGL building while ignoring the heat
transfer eect between spaces for HV ACs.
118
– Human subject experiments were conducted under a specifically controlled environ-
ment, which may result in biased results from human participants.
Although the Shapley value has been widely adopted for mathematically computing fair
individual allocations, human conceptions of its fairness to actual users in my domain have
not yet been explored.
The proposed algorithms were mainly evaluated in simulation, and the integrated agent has
been only deployed at the Doheny library as a pilot project in a limited fashion. Although the
simulation results clearly support the argument that the proposed methods have significant
potential in saving energy, the full-scale deployment will be eventually required to verify
the end-to-end operations of my agent in real commercial buildings.
So far, the eects of social norm-based feedback and monetary-based feedback on changing
people’s (habitual) behaviors have not been investigated thoroughly in this energy domain.
The social norm-based feedback on groups of human users has not been explored in my
work.
119
Bibliography
Karthik V . Aadithya, Balaraman Ravindran, Tomasz P. Michalak, and Nicholas R. Jennings.
Ecient computation of the shapley value for centrality in networks. In Proceedings of the 6th
international conference on Internet and network economics, WINE’10, pages 1–13, Berlin,
Heidelberg, 2010. Springer-Verlag.
W. Abrahmase, L. Steg, C. Vlek, and T. Rothengatter. A review of intervention studies aimed at
household energy conservation. J Environ. Psychol., 25:273–291, 2005.
S. Abras, S. Ploix, S. Pesty, and M. Jacomino. A multi–agent home automation system for power
management. In ICINCO, 2006.
S. Abras, S. Ploix, S. Pesty, and M. Jacomino. A multi-agent home automation system for power
management. Informatics in Control Automation and Robotics, 15:59–68, 2008.
Shabbir Ahmed, Alexander Shapiro, and Er Shapiro. The sample average approximation method
for stochastic programs with integer recourse. SIAM Journal of Optimization, 12:479–502,
2002.
Muddasser Alam, Sarvapali D Ramchurn, and Alex Rogers. Cooperative energy exchange for
the ecient use of energy and resources in remote communities. In Proceedings of the 2013
international conference on Autonomous agents and multi-agent systems, pages 731–738.
International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, 2013.
David Aldous. Exchangeability and related topics.
´
Ecole d’
´
Et´ e de Probabilit´ es de Saint-Flour
XIII?1983, pages 1–198, 1985.
K. Anderson, S. Lee, and C. Menassa. Eect of social network type on building occupant energy
use. In Buildsys, pages 17–24. ACM, 2012.
T.W. Athan and P.Y . Papalambros. A note on weighted criteria methods for compromise solutions
in multi-objective optimization. Eng. Optim., 27:155–176, 1996.
Yoram Bachrach, Evangelos Markakis, Ezra Resnick, Ariel D. Procaccia, Jerey S. Rosenschein,
and Amin Saberi. Approximating power indices: theoretical and empirical analysis. Autonomous
Agents and Multi-Agent Systems, 20(2):105–122, March 2010. ISSN 1387-2532.
Yoram Bachrach, Thore Graepel, Gjergji Kasneci, Michal Kosinski, and Jurgen Van Gael. Crowd
iq: aggregating opinions to boost performance. In Proceedings of the 11th International
Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems - Volume 1, AAMAS ’12, pages
535–542, Richland, SC, 2012. International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent
Systems. ISBN 0-9817381-1-7, 978-0-9817381-1-6.
120
Yoram Bachrach, Ely Porat, and Jerey S Rosenschein. Sharing rewards in cooperative connectivity
games. Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research, 47:281–311, 2013.
James Bagnell, Andrew Y Ng, and Je Schneider. Solving uncertain markov decision problems.
Robotics Institute, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, Tech. Rep. CMU-RI-TR-01-25,
2001.
Tanuja Bapat, Neha Sengupta, Sunil K. Ghai, Vijay Arya, Yedendra B. Shrinivasan, and Deva
Seetharam. User-sensitive scheduling of home appliances. In SIGCOMM, 2011.
R.S. Baron, P.H. Baron, and N. Miller. The relation between distraction and persuasion. Psycho-
logical Bulletin, 80(4):310, 1973.
EML Beale. On minimizing a convex function subject to linear inequalities. Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society. Series B (Methodological), pages 173–184, 1955.
S.W. Bither. Eects of distraction and commitment on the persuasiveness of television advertising.
Journal of Marketing Research, pages 1–5, 1972.
J.T. Cacioppo and R.E. Petty. Eects of message repetition on argument processing, recall, and
persuasion. Basic and Applied Social Psychology, 10(1):3–12, 1989.
B.J. Calder and B. Sternthal. Television commercial wearout: An information processing view.
Journal of Marketing Research, pages 173–186, 1980.
S. Caron and G. Kesidis. Incentive-based energy consumption scheduling algorithms for the smart
grid. In SmartGridComm, 2010.
A.R. Carrico and M. Riemer. Motivating energy conservation in the workplace: An evaluation of
the use of group-level feedback and peer education. J Environ. Psychol., 31, 2011.
Javier Castro, Daniel G´ omez, and Juan Tejada. Polynomial calculation of the shapley value based
on sampling. Computers & Operations Research, 36(5):1726–1730, 2009.
Georgios Chalkiadakis, Valentin Robu, Ramachandra Kota, Alex Rogers, and Nick Jennings.
Cooperatives of distributed energy resources for ecient virtual power plants. In AAMAS, 2011.
URLhttp://eprints.ecs.soton.ac.uk/21950/.
Krishnendu Chatterjee, Rupak Majumdar, and Thomas A. Henzinger. Markov decision processes
with multiple objectives. In STACS, 2006.
G. Conte and D. Scaradozzi. Viewing home automation systems as multiple agents systems. In
Multi-agent system for industrial and service robotics applications, RoboCUP, 2003.
George B Dantzig. Linear programming under uncertainty. Management Science, 1(3-4):197–206,
1955.
I. Das and J.E. Dennis. A closer look at drawbacks of minimizing weighted sums of objectives for
pareto set generation in multicriteria optimization problems. Struct. Optim., 14:63–69, 1997.
121
Karina Valdivia Delgado, Scott Sanner, Leliane Nunes de Barros, and Fabio G. Cozman. Ecient
solutions to factored MDPs with imprecise transition probabilities. In AAAI, 2009.
M. Fahrioglu and F. L. Alvardo. Designing incentive compatible contracts for eective demand
managements. IEEE Trans. Power Systems, 15:1255–1260, 2000.
Ahmad Faruqui, Sanem Sergici, and Ahmed Sharif. The impact of informational feedback on
energy consumption - a survey of the experimental evidence. Energy, 35, 2010.
Shaheen S. Fatima, Michael Wooldridge, and Nicholas R. Jennings. A linear approximation
method for the shapley value. Artif. Intell., 172(14):1673–1699, September 2008. ISSN
0004-3702.
A. Gallagher, T. Zimmerman, and S. Smith. Incremental scheduling to maximize quality in a
dynamic environment. In ICAPS, 2006.
Y . Gao, E. Tumwesigye, B. Cahill, and K. Menzel. Using data mining in optimization of building
energy consumption and thermal comfort management. In SEDM, 2010.
Enrico Gerding, Valentin Robu, Sebastian Stein, David Parkes, Alex Rogers, and Nick Jennings.
Online mechanism design for electric vehicle charging. In AAMAS, 2011. URL http://
eprints.ecs.soton.ac.uk/21907/.
Donald B Gillies. Solutions to general non-zero-sum games. Contributions to the Theory of
Games, 4:47–85, 1959.
Robert Givan, Sonia Leach, and Thomas Dean. Bounded-parameter Markov decision processes.
Artificial Intelligence, 2000.
G´ erard Hamiache. Associated consistency and shapley value. International Journal of Game
Theory, 30(2):279–289, 2001.
Kevin A Hassett and Gilbert E Metcalf. Energy tax credits and residential conservation investment:
Evidence from panel data. Journal of Public Economics, 57(2):201–217, 1995.
Shih-Chieh Hsieh. Fair transmission loss allocation based on equivalent current injection and
shapley value. In IEEE Power Engineering Society General Meeting, pages 6 pp.–, 2006.
F. Jazizadeh, A. Ghahramani, B. Becerik-Gerber, T. Kichkaylo, and M. Orosz. A human-
building interaction framework for personalized thermal comfort driven systems in oce
buildings. Journal of Computing in Civil Engineering, 2013a. doi: 10.1061/(ASCE)CP.
1943-5487.0000300. URLhttp://ascelibrary.org/doi/abs/10.1061/%28ASCE%29CP.
1943-5487.0000300.
Farrokh Jazizadeh, Georey Kavulya, Laura Klein, and Burcin Becerik-Gerber. Continuous
sensing of occupant perception of indoor ambient factors. In ASCE International Workshop on
Computing in Civil Engineering, 2011.
Farrokh Jazizadeh, Franco Moiso Marin, and Burcin Becerik-Gerber. A thermal preference
scale for personalized comfort profile identification via participatory sensing. Building and
Environment, 2013b.
122
Peter Kall and Stein W Wallace. Stochastic programming. John Wiley and Sons Ltd, 1994.
S. Kamboj, W. Kempton, and K. S. Decker. Deploying power grid-integrated electric vehicles as a
multi-agent system. In AAMAS, 2011.
P.A. Kattuman, R.J. Green, and J.W. Bialek. A tracing method for pricing inter-area electric-
ity trades. Cambridge working papers in economics, Faculty of Economics, University of
Cambridge, June 2001.
H. Ezzat Khalifa, Can Isik, and John F. III Dannenhoer. Energy eciency of distributed
environmental control systems. Technical Report DOE-ER63694-1, Syracuse Univ., 2006.
Samee U. Khan and Ishfaq Ahmad. A cooperative game theoretical technique for joint optimization
of energy consumption and response time in computational grids. IEEE Trans. Parallel Distrib.
Syst., 20(3):346–360, March 2009. ISSN 1045-9219.
J. Koski. Defectiveness of weighting method in multi-criterion optimization of structures. Commun.
Appl. Numer. Methods, 1:333–337, 1985.
J. Koski and R. Silvennoinen. Norm methods and partial weighting in multicriterion optimization
of structures. Int. J. Numer. Methods Eng., 24:1101–1121, 1987.
Jun-young Kwak, Pradeep Varakantham, Rajiv Maheswaran, Milind Tambe, Farrokh Jazizadeh,
Georey Kavulya, Laura Klein, Burcin Becerik-Gerber, Timothy Hayes, and Wendy Wood.
SA VES: A sustainable multiagent application to conserve building energy considering occupants.
In AAMAS, 2012a.
Jun-young Kwak, Pradeep Varakantham, Rajiv Maheswaran, Milind Tambe, Farrokh Jazizadeh,
Georey Kavulya, Laura Klein, Burcin Becerik-Gerber, Timothy Hayes, and Wendy Wood. Sus-
tainable multiagent application to conserve energy. In International Conference on Autonomous
Agents and Multiagent Systems (AAMAS) Demonstration Track, 2012b.
Jun-young Kwak, Pradeep Varakantham, Rajiv Maheswaran, Yu-Han Chang, Milind Tambe,
Burcin Becerik-Gerber, and Wendy Wood. TESLA: An extended study of an energy-saving
agent that leverages schedule flexibility. Journal of Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems
(JAAMAS), 2013a.
Jun-young Kwak, Pradeep Varakantham, Rajiv Maheswaran, Yu-Han Chang, Milind Tambe,
Burcin Becerik-Gerber, and Wendy Wood. Tesla: An energy-saving agent that leverages
schedule flexibility. In International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems
(AAMAS), 2013b.
Kevin Leyton-Brown and Yoav Shoham. Essentials of game theory: A concise multidisciplinary
introduction. Synthesis Lectures on Artificial Intelligence and Machine Learning, 2(1):1–88,
2008.
N. Li, G. Calis, and B. Becerik-Gerber. Measuring and monitoring occupancy with an RFID based
system for demand-driven HV AC operations. Journal of Automation in Construction, 24:89–99,
2012a.
123
N. Li, S. Li, B. Becerik-Gerber, and G. Calis. Deployment strategies and performance evaluation
of a virtual-tag-enabled indoor localization approach. ASCE Journal of Computing in Civil
Engineering, 26(5):574–583, 2012b.
Rajiv T Maheswaran, Milind Tambe, Emma Bowring, Jonathan P Pearce, and Pradeep Varakan-
tham. Taking dcop to the real world: Ecient complete solutions for distributed multi-event
scheduling. In Proceedings of the Third International Joint Conference on Autonomous Agents
and Multiagent Systems-Volume 1, pages 310–317. IEEE Computer Society, 2004.
A. Majumdar, D. H. Albonesi, and P. Bose. Energy-aware meeting scheduling algorithms for
smart buildings. In Buildsys, pages 161–168. ACM, 2012.
Sunil Mamidi, Yu-Han Chang, and Rajiv Maheswaran. Improving building energy eciency with
a network of sensing, learning and prediction agents. In AAMAS, 2012a.
Sunil Mamidi, Yu-Han Chang, and Rajiv Maheswaran. Improving building energy eciency
with a network of sensing, learning and prediction agents. In AAMAS, 2012b. URL http:
//cbg.isi.edu/wp-content/uploads/publications/3.pdf.
Irwin Mann and Shapley S. Llyod. Values of large games, iv: Evaluating the electoral college by
monte-carlo techniques. Technical report, The Rand Corporation, Santa Monica, CA, USA,
1960.
J.L. McCullough and T.M. Ostrom. Repetition of highly similar messages and attitude change.
Journal of Applied Psychology, 59(3):395, 1974.
A. Messac, C.P. Sukam, and E. Melachrinoudis. Aggregate objective functions and Pareto frontiers:
required relationships and practical implications. Optim. Eng., 1:171–188, 2000a.
A. Messac, G.J. Sundararaj, R.V . Tappeta, and J.E. Renaud. Ability of objective functions to
generate points on nonconvex pareto frontiers. AIAA Journal, 38:1084–1091, 2000b.
K. Miettinen. Nonlinear Multiobjective Optimization. Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1999.
Sam Miller, Sarvapali D. Ramchurn, and Alex Rogers. Optimal decentralised dispatch of embedded
generation in the smart grid. In AAMAS, 2012.
ZhengChun Mo and Ardeshir Mahdavi. An agent-based simulation-assisted approach to bi-lateral
building systems control. In IBPSA, 2003.
A.-H. Mohsenian-Rad and A. Leon-Garcia. Optimal residential load control with price prediction
in real-time electricity pricing environments. Smart Grid, IEEE Transaction on, 1(2):120–133,
2010.
A.-H. Mohsenian-Rad, V .W.S. Wong, J. Jatskevich, and R. Schober. Optimal and autonomous
incentivebased energy consumption scheduling algorithm for smart grid. In ISGT, 2010.
Mahesh Nagarajan, Greys Sosic, and Hao Zhang. Stable group purchasing organizations. Marshall
School of Business Working Paper No. FBE, pages 20–10, 2010.
Noam Nisan. Algorithmic game theory. Cambridge University Press, 2007.
124
C.L. Nordhielm. The influence of level of processing on advertising repetition eects. Journal of
consumer research, 29(3):371–382, 2002.
Wlodzimierz Ogryczak, Patrice Perny, and Paul Weng. A compromise programming approach to
multiobjective Markov decision processes. In MCDM, 2011.
A. Osyczka. An approach to multicriterion optimization problems for engineering design. Comput.
Methods Appl. Mech. Eng., 15:309–333, 1978.
Guillermo Owen. Multilinear extensions of games. Management Science, 18(5):64–79, January
1972. ISSN 0004-3702.
BK Pagnoncelli, S Ahmed, and A Shapiro. Sample average approximation method for chance con-
strained programming: theory and applications. Journal of optimization theory and applications,
142(2):399–416, 2009.
V . Pareto. Manuale di Economica Politica. Societa Editrice Libraria, 1906.
C. Pechmann and D.W. Stewart. Advertising repetition: A critical review of wearin and wearout.
Current issues and research in advertising, 1988.
L. Perez-Lombard, J. Ortiz, and C. Pout. A review on buildings energy consumption information.
Energy and Buildings, 40:394–398, 2008.
N. Policella, S. F. Smith, A. Cesta, and A. Oddi. Incremental scheduling to maximize quality in a
dynamic environment. In ICAPS, 2004.
Martin L Puterman. Markov decision processes: discrete stochastic dynamic programming, volume
414. Wiley. com, 2009.
S. D. Ramchurn, P. Vytelingum, A. Rogers, and N. R. Jennings. Agent-based control for decen-
tralised demand side management in the smart grid. In AAMAS, 2011.
D.T. Regan and J.B. Cheng. Distraction and attitude change: A resolution. Journal of Experimental
Social Psychology, 9(2):138–147, 1973.
Alex Rogers, Sasan Maleki, Siddhartha Ghosh, and Nicholas Jennings. Adaptive home heating
control through Gaussian process prediction and mathematical programming. In International
Workshop on Agent Technology for Energy Systems (ATES), 2011. URL http://eprints.
ecs.soton.ac.uk/22235/.
Nirmalya Roy, Abhishek Roy, and Sajal K. Das. Context-aware resource management in multi-
inhabitant smart homes: A nash h-learning based approach. In PerCom, 2006. ISBN 0-7695-
2518-0. doi: 10.1109/PERCOM.2006.18. URLhttp://portal.acm.org/citation.cfm?
id=1128015.1128338.
M.E. Salukvadze. Optimization of vector functionals, I, programming of optimal trajectories.
Avtomatika i Telemekhanika, 8:5–15, 1971a.
M.E. Salukvadze. Optimization of vector functionals, II, the analytic construction of optimal
controls. Avtomatika i Telemekhanika, 9:5–15, 1971b.
125
M. Santamouris, A. Argiriou, E. Dascalaki, C. Balaras, and A. Gaglia. Energy characteristics and
savings potential in oce buildings. Solar Energy, 52:59–66, 1994.
Paul Scerri, David V . Pynadath, and Milind Tambe. Towards adjustable autonomy for the real
world. JAIR, 17:171–228, 2002.
David Schmeidler. The nucleolus of a characteristic function game. SIAM Journal on applied
mathematics, 17(6):1163–1170, 1969.
D.W. Schumann, R.E. Petty, and D.S. Clemons. Predicting the eectiveness of dierent strategies
of advertising variation: A test of the repetition-variation hypotheses. Journal of Consumer
Research, pages 192–202, 1990.
Nathan Schurr, Janusz Marecki, and Milind Tambe. Improving adjustable autonomy strategies for
time-critical domains. In AAMAS, 2009.
Matteo Sereno. Cooperative game theory framework for energy ecient policies in wireless
networks. In Proceedings of the 3rd International Conference on Future Energy Systems: Where
Energy, Computing and Communication Meet, e-Energy ’12, pages 17:1–17:9, New York, NY ,
USA, 2012. ACM.
Alexander Shapiro, Darinka Dentcheva, and Andrzej Ruszczy´ nski. Lectures on stochastic pro-
gramming: modeling and theory, volume 9. Society for Industrial Mathematics, 2009.
Lloyd S. Shapley. A value for n-person games. Kuhn HW, Tucker AW, editors. Contributions to the
theory of games II, Annals of mathematics studies, 28:307–317, 1953.
H. Soh and Y . Demiris. Evolving policies for multi-reward partially observable markov deci-
sion processes (mr-pomdps). In Proceedings of the 13th annual conference on Genetic and
evolutionary computation, pages 713–720. ACM, 2011.
Kin Cheong Sou, James Weimer, Henrik Sandberg, and Karl Henrik Johansson. Scheduling smart
home appliances using mixed integer linear programming. In CDC-ECC, 2011.
W. Stadler. Initiators of multicriteria optimization. Recent Advances and Historical Development
of Vector Optimization, 294:3–25, 1987.
W. Stadler. Fundamentals of multicriteria optimization. Multicriteria Optimization in Engineering
and in the Sciences, pages 1–25, 1988.
W. Stadler. Caveats and boons of multicriteria optimization. Microcomput. Civ. Eng., 10:291–299,
1995.
W. Stadler and J.P. Dauer. Multicriteria optimization in engineering: a tutorial and survey.
Structural Optimization: Status and Promise, pages 211–249, 1992.
ASHRAE Standard. Standard 62-2001, ventilation for acceptable indoor air quality. American
Society of Heating, Refrigerating, and Air-Conditioning Engineers, Atlanta, www. ASHRAE.
org, 2001.
126
Sebastian Stein, Enrico Gerding, Valentin Robu, and Nick Jennings. A model-based online
mechanism with pre-commitment and its application to electric vehicle charging. In AAMAS,
2012. URLhttp://eprints.soton.ac.uk/273082/.
Evan Sultanik, Pragnesh Jay Modi, and William C Regli. On modeling multiagent task scheduling
as a distributed constraint optimization problem. In Proceedings of the 20th International Joint
Conference on Artificial Intelligence, pages 1531–1536, 2007.
H. S. Sun and S. E. Lee. Case study of data centers’ energy performance. Energy and Buildings,
38:522–533, 2006.
U.S. Department of Energy. Buildings energy data book. http://buildingsdatabook.eren.
doe.gov/, 2010.
U.S. Department of Labor. Average energy prices in the Los Angeles area. http://www.bls.
gov/ro9/cpilosa_energy.htm, 2012.
Stijn Vandael, Klaas De Craemer, Nelis Boucke, Tom Holvoet, and Geert Deconinck. Decentralized
balancing of a commercial portfolio with plug-in hybrid vehicles in a smart grid. In AAMAS,
2011.
T.L. Vincent and W.J. Grantham. Optimality in Parametric Systems. John Wiley & Sons, 1981.
Thomas V oice, Perukrishnen Vytelingum, Sarvapali Ramchurn, Alex Rogers, and Nick Jennings.
Decentralised control of micro-storage in the smart grid. In AAAI, 2011. URL http://
eprints.ecs.soton.ac.uk/22262/.
P. Vytelingum, T. D. V oice, S. D. Ramchurn, A. Rogers, and N. R. Jennings. Agent-based
micro-storage management for the smart grid. In AAMAS, 2010.
Jacques Wainer, Paulo Roberto Ferreira Jr., and Everton Rufino Constantino. Scheduling meetings
through multi-agent negotiations. Decision Support Systems, 44(1), 2007.
Chen Wang, M. de Groot, and P. Marendy. A service-oriented system for optimizing residential
energy use. In Web Services, IEEE International Conference on, 2009.
M.A. Wiering and E.D. De Jong. Computing optimal stationary policies for multi-objective markov
decision processes. In Approximate Dynamic Programming and Reinforcement Learning, 2007.
ADPRL 2007. IEEE International Symposium on, pages 158–165. IEEE, 2007.
W. Wood and D.T. Neal. A new look at habits and the habit? goal interface. Psychological Review,
114:843–863, 2007.
W. Wood and D.T. Neal. The habitual consumer. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 19:579–592,
2009.
Gang Xiong, Chen Chen, Shalinee Kishore, and Aylin Yener. Smart (in-home) power scheduling
for demand response on the smart grid. In ISGT, 2011.
K.P Yoon and C.-L. Hwang. Multiple Attribute Decision Making, An Introduction. Sage Publica-
tions, 1995.
127
L.A. Zadeh. Optimality and non-scalar-valued performance criteria. IEEE Trans. Autom. Control,
8:59–60, 1963.
M. Zima-Bockarjova, J. Matevosyan, M. Zima, and L. Soder. Sharing of profit from coordinated
operation planning and bidding of hydro and wind power. Power Systems, IEEE Transactions
on, 25(3):1663–1673, 2010a.
M. Zima-Bockarjova, A. Sauhats, G. Vempers, and I. Tereskina. On application of the cooperative
game theory to energy supply system planning. In Energy Market (EEM), 2010 7th International
Conference on the European, pages 1–6, 2010b.
128
Appendix: Properties of Shapley Value to Axiomatize Fairness
In Chapter 5, I mentioned that my approximation algorithms theoretically satisfy the dummy
player and additivity properties. I thus provide a formal proof to show that in this appendix.
Let us recall that the Shapley value can be expressed in terms of all possible orders of the
players in N. Let O :f1;:::; ng!f1;:::; ng be a permutation that assigns to each position k the
player O(k). Let us denote by(N) the set of all possible permutations with player set N. Given
a permutation O, let us denote by P
i
(O) the set of predecessors of the player i in the order O
(i.e., P
i
(O) =fO(1);:::; O(k 1)g; if i = O(k)). Thus, the Shapley value can be expressed in the
following way:
i
(N; v) =
X
O2(N)
1
n!
v
O
(i); i = 1;:::; n: (1)
where
v
O
(i) = v(P
i
(O)[ i) v(P
i
(O)), which is the marginal contribution of player i given a
permutation O.
Proposition 1. Dummy player: Consider a coalitional game (N; v). If a player i2 N is a dummy,
then
i
(N; v) = 0.
Proof. Take an arbitrary permutation O. We have v(P
i
(O)[ i) = v(P
i
(O)) as player i is a dummy.
Thus,
v
O
(i) = 0. As this holds for any O2(N), we have
i
(N; v) = 0.
For ApproShapley, we now consider m sampled permutations
m
(N)2(N). Likewise, since
the same property holds for any O2
m
(N), we still have
i
(N; v) = 0.
For graph partitioning, let S
1
and S
2
are partitions (i.e., independent) of N (i.e., N = S
1
[
S
2
; S
1
\ S
2
=;; S
1
, S
2
). If player i2 S
1
is a dummy, then
i
(N; v) =
i
(S
1
[ S
2
; v) (* by definition)
=
i
(S
1
; v) (* S
1
and S
2
are independent; Lemma 2)
= 0 (* for any permutation O2(S
1
),
v
O
(i) = 0)
Likewise, if player i2 S
2
is a dummy,
i
(N; v) =
i
(S
1
[ S
2
; v) =
i
(S
2
; v) = 0.
Thus, any combination of our approximation methods hold the dummy player property.
Proposition 2. Additivity: Consider two characteristic functions v
1
and v
2
over the same set of
players N. Then for any player i2 N, we have
i
(N; v
1
+ v
2
) =
i
(N; v
1
) +
i
(N; v
2
).
129
Proof. Let v
+
be the characteristic function v
1
+ v
2
. Given a player i2 N and a permutation O, let
+
O
(i) = v
+
(P
i
(O)[ i) v
+
(P
i
(O)). Then,
+
O
(i) = v
+
(P
i
(O)[ i) v
+
(P
i
(O))
= [v
1
(P
i
(O)[ i) + v
2
(P
i
(O)[ i)] [v
1
(P
i
(O)) + v
2
(P
i
(O))]
= [v
1
(P
i
(O)[ i) v
1
(P
i
(O))] + [v
2
(P
i
(O)[ i) v
2
(P
i
(O))]
=
v
1
O
(i) +
v
2
O
(i):
Thus, we obtain
i
(N; v
1
+ v
2
) =
i
(N; v
+
) =
1
n!
X
O2(N)
+
O
(i)
=
1
n!
X
O2(N)
(
v
1
O
(i) +
v
2
O
(i))
=
i
(N; v
1
) +
i
(N; v
2
):
For ApproShapley, we now consider m sampled permutations
m
(N)2(N). Similarly, for
any O2
m
(N),
+
O
(i) =
v
1
O
(i) +
v
2
O
(i). Thus,
i
(N; v
1
+ v
2
) =
1
m!
X
O2
m
(N)
+
O
(i)
=
1
m!
X
O2
m
(N)
(
v
1
O
(i) +
v
2
O
(i))
=
i
(N; v
1
) +
i
(N; v
2
):
For graph partitioning, let S
1
and S
2
are partitions (i.e., independent) of N (i.e., N = S
1
[
S
2
; S
1
\ S
2
=;; S
1
, S
2
). If player i2 S
1
, then
i
(N; v
1
+ v
2
) =
i
(S
1
[ S
2
; v
1
+ v
2
) (* by definition)
=
i
(S
1
; v
1
+ v
2
) (* S
1
and S
2
are independent; Lemma 2)
=
i
(S
1
; v
1
) +
i
(S
1
; v
2
) (* for any O2(S
1
),
+
O
(i) =
v
1
O
(i) +
v
2
O
(i))
=
i
(S
1
[ S
2
; v
1
) +
i
(S
1
[ S
2
; v
2
) (* S
1
and S
2
are independent; Lemma 2)
=
i
(N; v
1
) +
i
(N; v
2
) (* by definition)
Likewise, if player i2 S
2
,
i
(N; v
1
+ v
2
) =
i
(N; v
1
) +
i
(N; v
2
).
Thus, any combination of our approximation methods hold the additivity property.
130
Abstract (if available)
Abstract
Agent‐based systems for energy conservation are now a growing area of research in multiagent systems, with applications ranging from energy management and control on the smart grid, to energy conservation in residential buildings, to energy generation and dynamic negotiations in distributed rural communities. Contributing to this area, my thesis presents new agent‐based models and algorithms aiming to conserve energy in commercial buildings. ❧ More specifically, my thesis provides three sets of algorithmic contributions. First, I provide online predictive scheduling algorithms to handle massive numbers of meeting/event scheduling requests considering flexibility, which is a novel concept for capturing generic user constraints while optimizing the desired objective. Second, I present a novel BM‐MDP (Bounded-parameter Multi‐objective Markov Decision Problem) model and robust algorithms for multi‐objective optimization under uncertainty both at the planning and execution time. The BM‐MDP model and its robust algorithms are useful in (re)scheduling events to achieve energy efficiency in the presence of uncertainty over user’s preferences. Third, when multiple users contribute to energy savings, fair division of credit for such savings to incentivize users for their energy saving activities arises as an important question. I appeal to cooperative game theory and specifically to the concept of Shapley value for this fair division. Unfortunately, scaling up this Shapley value computation is a major hindrance in practice. Therefore, I present novel approximation algorithms to efficiently compute the Shapley value based on sampling and partitions and to speed up the characteristic function computation. ❧ These new models have not only advanced the state of the art in multiagent algorithms, but have actually been successfully integrated within agents dedicated to energy efficiency: SAVES, TESLA and THINC. SAVES focuses on the day‐to‐day energy consumption of individuals and groups in commercial buildings by reactively suggesting energy conserving alternatives. TESLA takes a long‐range planning perspective and optimizes overall energy consumption of a large number of group events or meetings together. THINC provides an end‐to‐end integration within a single agent of energy efficient scheduling, rescheduling and credit allocation. While SAVES, TESLA and THINC thus differ in their scope and applicability, they demonstrate the utility of agent-based systems in actually reducing energy consumption in commercial buildings. ❧ I evaluate my algorithms and agents using extensive analysis on data from over 110,000 real meetings/events at multiple educational buildings including the main libraries at the University of Southern California. I also provide results on simulations and real‐world experiments, clearly demonstrating the power of agent technology to assist human users in saving energy in commercial buildings.
Linked assets
University of Southern California Dissertations and Theses
Conceptually similar
PDF
Addressing uncertainty in Stackelberg games for security: models and algorithms
PDF
Planning with continuous resources in agent systems
PDF
Point cloud data fusion of RGB and thermal information for advanced building envelope modeling in support of energy audits for large districts
PDF
Human adversaries in security games: integrating models of bounded rationality and fast algorithms
PDF
User-centric smart sensing for non-intrusive electricity consumption disaggregation in buildings
PDF
Handling attacker’s preference in security domains: robust optimization and learning approaches
PDF
The human element: addressing human adversaries in security domains
PDF
Understanding human-building interactions through perceptual decision-making processes
PDF
Automatic detection and optimization of energy optimizable UIs in Android applications using program analysis
PDF
Real-world evaluation and deployment of wildlife crime prediction models
PDF
Energy proportional computing for multi-core and many-core servers
PDF
Designing‐in performance: energy simulation feedback for early stage design decision making
PDF
Landscape and building solar loads: development of a computer-based tool to aid in the design of landscape to reduce solar gain and energy consumption in low-rise residential buildings
PDF
Cache analysis and techniques for optimizing data movement across the cache hierarchy
Asset Metadata
Creator
Kwak, Jun‐young
(author)
Core Title
The power of flexibility: autonomous agents that conserve energy in commercial buildings
School
Viterbi School of Engineering
Degree
Doctor of Philosophy
Degree Program
Computer Science
Publication Date
01/23/2014
Defense Date
11/01/2013
Publisher
University of Southern California
(original),
University of Southern California. Libraries
(digital)
Tag
energy conservation,fair division,multiagent systems,OAI-PMH Harvest,planning/scheduling under uncertainty,robust optimization,user incentivization
Format
application/pdf
(imt)
Language
English
Contributor
Electronically uploaded by the author
(provenance)
Advisor
Tambe, Milind (
committee chair
), Becerik-Gerber, Burcin (
committee member
), Chang, Yu-Han (
committee member
), Maheswaran, Rajiv (
committee member
), Varakantham, Pradeep (
committee member
), Wood, Wendy (
committee member
)
Creator Email
inducer@gmail.com,junyounk@usc.edu
Permanent Link (DOI)
https://doi.org/10.25549/usctheses-c3-360260
Unique identifier
UC11295879
Identifier
etd-KwakJunyou-2232.pdf (filename),usctheses-c3-360260 (legacy record id)
Legacy Identifier
etd-KwakJunyou-2232.pdf
Dmrecord
360260
Document Type
Dissertation
Format
application/pdf (imt)
Rights
Kwak, Jun‐young
Type
texts
Source
University of Southern California
(contributing entity),
University of Southern California Dissertations and Theses
(collection)
Access Conditions
The author retains rights to his/her dissertation, thesis or other graduate work according to U.S. copyright law. Electronic access is being provided by the USC Libraries in agreement with the a...
Repository Name
University of Southern California Digital Library
Repository Location
USC Digital Library, University of Southern California, University Park Campus MC 2810, 3434 South Grand Avenue, 2nd Floor, Los Angeles, California 90089-2810, USA
Tags
energy conservation
fair division
multiagent systems
planning/scheduling under uncertainty
robust optimization
user incentivization